IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/pubcho/v35y1980i4p421-436.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Preference expression and misrepresentation in points voting schemes

Author

Listed:
  • Shmuel Nitzan
  • Jacob Paroush
  • Shlomo Lampert

Abstract

This paper focuses on two properties of points voting schemes: their vulnerability to preference misrepresentation and their potential for preference expression. In the spirit of the seminal work of Buchanan and Tullock [2], this dual criterion might be used for the choice of an optimal points voting scheme when the above two aspects only are considered. Unlike recent treatment of the manipulability phenomenon, Gardenfors [3], Gibbard [4], Satterthwaite [8], we do suggest measures for the immunity to mispresentation of a given method. The first measure I[X, f)] is interpreted as a lower bound for δ-manipulation. In other words, I[(X, f)]=c implies that there exists at least one preference profile [x ij ] ∈ X, such that δ-manipulation is possible for δ > c. The second measure K ranges from 0 to 1, and it is interpreted as the relative frequency of preference profiles in X under which the scheme is immune. Another measure D is proposed for the potential of preference expression under each variation. This measure counts the number of possible preference configurations under the scheme (X, f). The use of this measure for the comparison of two voting schemes (T, f), (Z, f) is especially meaningful whenever T ⊂ Z. This approach is illustrated by five variations of the points voting scheme: the well-known points voting method, the Borda scores method, the plurality rule, the federative plurality rule and a dictatorial type voting scheme. It is shown that, as these variations become more restrictive in terms of preference expression (D decreases), they tend to be more immune to individual preference misrepresentation (I increases). We conjecture, first, that a similar relationship will be generally obtained for variations of the points voting method, and, second, that such a relationship also exists between K and D. Finally, two comments with respect to the commonly used plurality rule are now in order. First, this rule is associated with moderate values of both measures, D(V 3 )=m n and I(V 3 )=1/2. Roughly speaking, it can be considered a ‘reasonable’ voting scheme for a society, or committee, which is ‘equally demanding’ in terms of both criteria. Second, the definition of misrepresentation used in this paper, takes into account misrepresentation of preferences with no restriction on the type of motivations for such a behavior. An alternative, and more common, definition deals only with preference misrevelations which are consistent with the sincere preferences of the manipulator, i.e., the winning alternative under the reported preference profile has to be preferred to the outcome of the sincere profile from the non sincere voter's point of view. Obviously, vulnerability to manipulation implies vulnerability to misrepresentation but the converse is not true. Also notice that if the definition of misrepresentation is replaced by that of manipulation, then plurality becomes perfectly immune, since no voter can act contrary to his sincere preferences and alter the social choice in his favor. Copyright Martinus Nijhoff Publishers bv 1980

Suggested Citation

  • Shmuel Nitzan & Jacob Paroush & Shlomo Lampert, 1980. "Preference expression and misrepresentation in points voting schemes," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 35(4), pages 421-436, January.
  • Handle: RePEc:kap:pubcho:v:35:y:1980:i:4:p:421-436
    DOI: 10.1007/BF00128121
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://hdl.handle.net/10.1007/BF00128121
    Download Restriction: Access to full text is restricted to subscribers.

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1007/BF00128121?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Gibbard, Allan, 1973. "Manipulation of Voting Schemes: A General Result," Econometrica, Econometric Society, vol. 41(4), pages 587-601, July.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Steven Brams & Peter Fishburn & Samuel Merrill, 1988. "The responsiveness of approval voting: Comments on Saari and Van Newenhizen," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 59(2), pages 121-131, November.
    2. Morton, Rebecca B. & Piovesan, Marco & Tyran, Jean-Robert, 2019. "The dark side of the vote: Biased voters, social information, and information aggregation through majority voting," Games and Economic Behavior, Elsevier, vol. 113(C), pages 461-481.
    3. Pivato, Marcus, 2006. "Approximate implementation of Relative Utilitarianism via Groves-Clarke pivotal voting with virtual money," MPRA Paper 627, University Library of Munich, Germany.

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Erlanson, Albin & Szwagrzak, Karol, 2013. "Strategy-Proof Package Assignment," Working Papers 2013:43, Lund University, Department of Economics.
    2. Felix Brandt & Patrick Lederer & René Romen, 2024. "Relaxed notions of Condorcet-consistency and efficiency for strategyproof social decision schemes," Social Choice and Welfare, Springer;The Society for Social Choice and Welfare, vol. 63(1), pages 19-55, August.
    3. Bock, Hans-Hermann & Day, William H. E. & McMorris, F. R., 1998. "Consensus rules for committee elections," Mathematical Social Sciences, Elsevier, vol. 35(3), pages 219-232, May.
    4. Pablo Guillen & Róbert F. Veszteg, 2021. "Strategy-proofness in experimental matching markets," Experimental Economics, Springer;Economic Science Association, vol. 24(2), pages 650-668, June.
    5. Marco LiCalzi, 2022. "Bipartite choices," Decisions in Economics and Finance, Springer;Associazione per la Matematica, vol. 45(2), pages 551-568, December.
    6. Dietrich, Franz & List, Christian, 2007. "Strategy-Proof Judgment Aggregation," Economics and Philosophy, Cambridge University Press, vol. 23(3), pages 269-300, November.
    7. John C. McCabe-Dansted & Arkadii Slinko, 2006. "Exploratory Analysis of Similarities Between Social Choice Rules," Group Decision and Negotiation, Springer, vol. 15(1), pages 77-107, January.
    8. James Schummer, 1999. "Almost-dominant Strategy Implementation," Discussion Papers 1278, Northwestern University, Center for Mathematical Studies in Economics and Management Science.
    9. Aleskerov, Fuad & Karabekyan, Daniel & Sanver, M. Remzi & Yakuba, Vyacheslav, 2012. "On the manipulability of voting rules: The case of 4 and 5 alternatives," Mathematical Social Sciences, Elsevier, vol. 64(1), pages 67-73.
    10. Lirong Xia, 2020. "How Likely Are Large Elections Tied?," Papers 2011.03791, arXiv.org, revised Jul 2021.
    11. Dindar, Hayrullah & Lainé, Jean, 2017. "Manipulation of single-winner large elections by vote pairing," Economics Letters, Elsevier, vol. 161(C), pages 105-107.
    12. Barbera, S. & Bossert, W. & Pattanaik, P.K., 2001. "Ranking Sets of Objects," Cahiers de recherche 2001-02, Centre interuniversitaire de recherche en économie quantitative, CIREQ.
    13. Brandt, Felix & Saile, Christian & Stricker, Christian, 2022. "Strategyproof social choice when preferences and outcomes may contain ties," Journal of Economic Theory, Elsevier, vol. 202(C).
    14. Shinji Ohseto, 2006. "Characterizations of strategy-proof and fair mechanisms for allocating indivisible goods," Economic Theory, Springer;Society for the Advancement of Economic Theory (SAET), vol. 29(1), pages 111-121, September.
    15. Jeff Strnad, 2024. "Economic DAO Governance: A Contestable Control Approach," Papers 2403.16980, arXiv.org, revised Jun 2024.
    16. Franz Dietrich & Christian List, 2024. "The impossibility of non-manipulable probability aggregation," Université Paris1 Panthéon-Sorbonne (Post-Print and Working Papers) halshs-04405495, HAL.
    17. Souvik Roy & Soumyarup Sadhukhan, 2019. "A characterization of random min–max domains and its applications," Economic Theory, Springer;Society for the Advancement of Economic Theory (SAET), vol. 68(4), pages 887-906, November.
    18. Samet, Dov & Schmeidler, David, 2003. "Between liberalism and democracy," Journal of Economic Theory, Elsevier, vol. 110(2), pages 213-233, June.
    19. Mizukami, Hideki & Saijo, Tatsuyoshi & Wakayama, Takuma, 2003. "Strategy-Proof Sharing," Working Papers 1170, California Institute of Technology, Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences.
    20. Bruno Frey, 2011. "Tullock challenges: happiness, revolutions, and democracy," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 148(3), pages 269-281, September.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:kap:pubcho:v:35:y:1980:i:4:p:421-436. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Sonal Shukla or Springer Nature Abstracting and Indexing (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.springer.com .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.