IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/bla/revpol/v39y2022i5p674-697.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

How Ostrom's design principles apply to large‐scale commons: Cooperation over international river basins

Author

Listed:
  • Geiguen Shin

Abstract

Many conventional studies on common‐pool resources (CPRs) have examined the governance of local resources such as fisheries, forests, grazing systems, irrigation systems, agriculture, water resources, and land tenure. However, a limited selection of recent studies has been interested in large‐scale commons such as climate change, air pollution, and transboundary disputes. Despite Ostrom's design principles (DPs) providing a robust framework for solving CPR problems, there have been relatively few empirical challenges examining the effect of DPs on CPRs, especially in the large‐scale commons. This paper examines how Ostrom's DPs are applied to international commons that may cause complicated disputes among states. The case being studied is international rivers as international commons. Based on binary logit analysis, this research found that four of Ostrom's DPs—clear boundary, operational rules, monitoring system, and multi‐level governance—are positively associated with success in managing the international river commons (IRCs) as a CPR. Additionally, the results from fuzzy‐set Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) partially indicate that the co‐occurrence of monitoring, conflict mechanisms, and multi‐level governance would lead to more successful IRCs. 许多关于公共池塘资源(CPRs)的传统研究分析了地方资源的治理,例如渔业、林业、放牧系统、灌溉系统、农业、水资源和土地使用权。不过,近期鲜有研究聚焦于大型公共资源的治理,例如气候变化、空气污染和跨边界争端。尽管奥斯特罗姆的设计原则(DPs)为解决CPR问题提供了稳健框架,但分析DPs对CPRs产生的效果、尤其针对大型公共资源的实证研究相对较少。本文分析了奥斯特罗姆的设计原则如何应用于国际公共资源,后者可能造成国与国之间的复杂争端。将国际河流作为国际公共资源进行案例研究。基于二元logit分析,本研究发现,奥斯特罗姆的设计原则中有四项与成功管理国际河流这一公共资源(IRCs)呈正相关,这四项原则分别是:清晰边界、操作性规则、监督系统和多层治理。此外,模糊集定性比较分析(QCA)部分表明,监督、冲突机制和多层治理的共同出现将导致更为成功的IRCs。 Muchos estudios convencionales sobre recursos de uso común (CPR) han examinado la gobernanza de los recursos locales como la pesca, los bosques, los sistemas de pastoreo, los sistemas de riego, la agricultura, los recursos hídricos y la tenencia de la tierra. Sin embargo, una selección limitada de estudios recientes se ha interesado en bienes comunes a gran escala como el cambio climático, la contaminación del aire y las disputas transfronterizas. A pesar de que los principios de diseño (PD) de Ostrom proporcionan un marco sólido para resolver problemas de CPR, ha habido relativamente pocos desafíos empíricos que examinen el efecto de los PD en los CPR, especialmente en los bienes comunes a gran escala. Este documento examina cómo se aplican los PD de Ostrom a los bienes comunes internacionales que pueden causar disputas complicadas entre los estados. El caso que se estudia son los ríos internacionales como bienes comunes internacionales. Basado en el análisis logit binario, esta investigación encontró que cuatro de los DP de Ostrom (límites claros, reglas operativas, sistema de monitoreo y gobernanza multinivel) están asociados positivamente con el éxito en la gestión de los recursos comunes de los ríos internacionales (IRC) como CPR. Además, los resultados del Análisis Comparativo Cualitativo (QCA) de conjunto difuso indican parcialmente que la coexistencia del monitoreo, los mecanismos de conflicto y la gobernanza multinivel conducirían a CRI más exitosos.

Suggested Citation

  • Geiguen Shin, 2022. "How Ostrom's design principles apply to large‐scale commons: Cooperation over international river basins," Review of Policy Research, Policy Studies Organization, vol. 39(5), pages 674-697, September.
  • Handle: RePEc:bla:revpol:v:39:y:2022:i:5:p:674-697
    DOI: 10.1111/ropr.12457
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://doi.org/10.1111/ropr.12457
    Download Restriction: no

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1111/ropr.12457?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Easter, K. William & Cortner, H.J. & Seasholes, K. & Woodard, G.C., 1995. "Selecting Appropriate Water Policies," Policy Briefs 11908, Environmental and Natural Resources Policy Training Project.
    2. Elinor Ostrom, 2000. "Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms," Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, vol. 14(3), pages 137-158, Summer.
    3. P. B. Anand, 2004. "Financing the Provision of Global Public Goods," The World Economy, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 27(2), pages 215-237, February.
    4. Scott Barrett & Robert Stavins, 2003. "Increasing Participation and Compliance in International Climate Change Agreements," International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, Springer, vol. 3(4), pages 349-376, December.
    5. Levine, Arielle & Richmond, Laurie, 2015. "Using common-pool resource design principles to assess the viability of community-based fisheries co-management systems in American Samoa and Hawai’i," Marine Policy, Elsevier, vol. 62(C), pages 9-17.
    6. Yandle, Tracy, 2003. "The challenge of building successful stakeholder organizations: New Zealand's experience in developing a fisheries co-management regime," Marine Policy, Elsevier, vol. 27(2), pages 179-192, March.
    7. Salter, Alexander William & Tarko, Vlad, 2019. "Governing the banking system: an assessment of resilience based on Elinor Ostrom's design principles," Journal of Institutional Economics, Cambridge University Press, vol. 15(3), pages 505-519, June.
    8. Morrow, Christopher E. & Hull, Rebecca Watts, 1996. "Donor-initiated common pool resource institutions: The case of the Yanesha Forestry Cooperative," World Development, Elsevier, vol. 24(10), pages 1641-1657, October.
    9. Nguyen Thi Quynh, Chi & Schilizzi, Steven & Hailu, Atakelty & Iftekhar, Sayed, 2020. "Vietnam’s Territorial Use Rights for Fisheries: How do they perform against Ostrom’s institutional design principles?," World Development Perspectives, Elsevier, vol. 17(C).
    10. Coleen Fox & Chris Sneddon, 2005. "Flood Pulses, International Watercourse Law, and Common Pool Resources: a Case Study of the Mekong Lowlands," WIDER Working Paper Series RP2005-20, World Institute for Development Economic Research (UNU-WIDER).
    11. Marc Jeuland & Xun Wu & Dale Whittington, 2017. "Infrastructure development and the economics of cooperation in the Eastern Nile," Water International, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 42(2), pages 121-141, February.
    12. Abbott, Kenneth W. & Snidal, Duncan, 2000. "Hard and Soft Law in International Governance," International Organization, Cambridge University Press, vol. 54(3), pages 421-456, July.
    13. Sirak Robele Gari & Alice Newton & John D. Icely & Maria Mar Delgado-Serrano, 2017. "An Analysis of the Global Applicability of Ostrom’s Design Principles to Diagnose the Functionality of Common-Pool Resource Institutions," Sustainability, MDPI, vol. 9(7), pages 1-17, July.
    14. Nishtman Karimi & Kobe Boussauw & Farzad Karimi, 2020. "The shifted ownership regime of a common-pool resource: the case of water exploitation in Sanandaj County, Iran," Water International, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 45(7-8), pages 765-787, November.
    15. Cinner, Joshua E. & Wamukota, Andrew & Randriamahazo, Herilala & Rabearisoa, Ando, 2009. "Toward institutions for community-based management of inshore marine resources in the Western Indian Ocean," Marine Policy, Elsevier, vol. 33(3), pages 489-496, May.
    16. Wijkman, Per Magnus, 1982. "Managing the global commons," International Organization, Cambridge University Press, vol. 36(3), pages 511-536, July.
    17. Gary D. Libecap, 2014. "Addressing Global Environmental Externalities: Transaction Costs Considerations," Journal of Economic Literature, American Economic Association, vol. 52(2), pages 424-479, June.
    18. Pichamon Yeophantong, 2017. "River activism, policy entrepreneurship and transboundary water disputes in Asia," Water International, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 42(2), pages 163-186, February.
    19. Warwick J. McKibbin & Peter J. Wilcoxen, 2002. "The Role of Economics in Climate Change Policy," Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, vol. 16(2), pages 107-129, Spring.
    20. Sandstrom, Camilla & Widmark, Camilla, 2007. "Stakeholders' perceptions of consultations as tools for co-management -- A case study of the forestry and reindeer herding sectors in northern Sweden," Forest Policy and Economics, Elsevier, vol. 10(1-2), pages 25-35, December.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Sirak Robele Gari & Alice Newton & John D. Icely & Maria Mar Delgado-Serrano, 2017. "An Analysis of the Global Applicability of Ostrom’s Design Principles to Diagnose the Functionality of Common-Pool Resource Institutions," Sustainability, MDPI, vol. 9(7), pages 1-17, July.
    2. Maximilian S. T. Wanner, 0. "The effectiveness of soft law in international environmental regimes: participation and compliance in the Hyogo Framework for Action," International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, Springer, vol. 0, pages 1-20.
    3. Stavins, Robert, 2004. "Can an Effective Global Climate Treaty be Based on Sound Science, Rational Economics, and Pragmatic Politics?," Working Paper Series rwp04-020, Harvard University, John F. Kennedy School of Government.
    4. Adrian Amelung, 2016. "Das "Paris-Agreement": Durchbruch der Top-Down-Klimaschutzverhandlungen im Kreise der Vereinten Nationen," Otto-Wolff-Institut Discussion Paper Series 03/2016, Otto-Wolff-Institut für Wirtschaftsordnung, Köln, Deutschland.
    5. Maximilian S. T. Wanner, 2021. "The effectiveness of soft law in international environmental regimes: participation and compliance in the Hyogo Framework for Action," International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, Springer, vol. 21(1), pages 113-132, March.
    6. Sheila M. Olmstead & Robert N. Stavins, 2012. "Three Key Elements of a Post-2012 International Climate Policy Architecture," Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, vol. 6(1), pages 65-85.
    7. Hansjürgens, Bernd, 2008. "Internationale Klimapolitik nach Kyoto: Architekturen und Institutionen," UFZ Discussion Papers 10/2008, Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research (UFZ), Division of Social Sciences (ÖKUS).
    8. Marco Grasso, 2004. "Climate change: the global public good," Others 0405010, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    9. Bonye, Samuel Ziem & Yiridomoh, Gordon Yenglier & Nsiah, Vivian, 2023. "Multi-stakeholder actors in resource management in Ghana: Dynamics of community-state collaboration in resource use management of the Mole National Park, Larabanga," Forest Policy and Economics, Elsevier, vol. 154(C).
    10. Aldy, Joseph E. & Barrett, Scott & Stavins, Robert N., 2003. "13 + 1: A Comparison of Global Climate Change Policy Architectures," Discussion Papers 10541, Resources for the Future.
    11. Wu, Pei-Ing & Chen, Chai Tzu & Cheng, Pei-Ching & Liou, Je-Liang, 2014. "Climate game analyses for CO2 emission trading among various world organizations," Economic Modelling, Elsevier, vol. 36(C), pages 441-446.
    12. Maamoun, Nada, 2021. "IEAs and compliance: Do treaty linkages play a role?," ILE Working Paper Series 43, University of Hamburg, Institute of Law and Economics.
    13. Djordjija Petkoski & Danielle Warren & William Laufer, 2009. "Collective Strategies in Fighting Corruption: Some Intuitions and Counter Intuitions," Journal of Business Ethics, Springer, vol. 88(4), pages 815-822, October.
    14. Olmstead, Sheila & Stavins, Robert, 2006. "An International Architecture for the Post-Kyoto Era," Working Paper Series rwp06-009, Harvard University, John F. Kennedy School of Government.
    15. Todd Sandler, 2015. "Collective action: fifty years later," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 164(3), pages 195-216, September.
    16. Cameron Hepburn, 2006. "Regulation by Prices, Quantities, or Both: A Review of Instrument Choice," Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Oxford University Press and Oxford Review of Economic Policy Limited, vol. 22(2), pages 226-247, Summer.
    17. Alló, Maria & Loureiro, Maria L., 2016. "Evaluating the fulfillment of the principles of collective action in practice: A case study from Galicia (NW Spain)," Forest Policy and Economics, Elsevier, vol. 73(C), pages 1-9.
    18. Phulkerd, Sirinya & Sacks, Gary & Vandevijvere, Stefanie & Worsley, Anthony & Lawrence, Mark, 2017. "Barriers and potential facilitators to the implementation of government policies on front-of-pack food labeling and restriction of unhealthy food advertising in Thailand," Food Policy, Elsevier, vol. 71(C), pages 101-110.
    19. Hugh-Jones, David & Reinstein, David, 2012. "Anonymous rituals," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Elsevier, vol. 81(2), pages 478-489.
    20. Karla Hoff & Mayuresh Kshetramade & Ernst Fehr, 2011. "Caste and Punishment: the Legacy of Caste Culture in Norm Enforcement," Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, vol. 121(556), pages 449-475, November.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:bla:revpol:v:39:y:2022:i:5:p:674-697. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Wiley Content Delivery (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/ipsonea.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.