IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/wii/cprofi/19.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Serbia and Montenegro: Transition with Organized Crime

Author

Listed:

Abstract

Serbia and Montenegro (S&M) is the Union of these two states that has emerged from the Federal Republic of Yugoslavia. That is only the beginning of the constitutional development that may take some time to be finished. The final outcome is most likely to be two independent states. It is probably the European Union (EU) that is the most interested in the preservation of S&M - partly because it wants to minimize the number of small states as future members and partly because it is not ready to address the issue of Kosovo, which, it is believed, would immediately follow once S&M dissolves. Thus, at the moment, S&M has been given a trial period of about three years to build up a functional state-like union. Chances for success are slim. The additional reason that S&M has little chance to survive is the pressing need to speed up the process of state- and institution-building. This mainly means the introduction of the rule of law. The urgency of this task has become evident after the assassination of the prime minister of Serbia, Mr. Zoran Djindjic. In its aftermath, it became clear that Serbia is a captured state. This is the inheritance from the Milo¿evic era. However, the post-Milo¿evic governments in Yugoslavia and Serbia chose the strategy of appeasement in many crucial areas, including that of dealing with the organized crime. They apparently believed that the progress of reforms and transition would take care of organized crime. In other words, they seem to have believed that transition with organized crime is possible. In that, they were brutally proved wrong. The situation in Montenegro is different, though the problems with organized crime are quite serious. It seems, however, that those are dealt with through corruption rather than through partnership. That does not mean that the problems with the introduction of the rule of law are not daunting there, too - especially because of the high level of informal economic activities or, rather, of the dependence of a large number of people on informal activities for their income. This problem is aggravated by the fact that the process of transition has still a long way to go and it will take some time before the country moves to the path of sustainable growth. Reforms in Serbia and Montenegro have been implemented separately, are at different stages, and are quite possibly incompatible. Montenegro relies, at least in principle, on liberalization, as this is a very small economy and can hardly grow if it is not increasingly opened. Serbia, however, relies on a strategy which sees a significant role for the state. This difference in strategies, though not necessarily in the actual economic situation, has led to probably insurmountable differences in trade policies. Montenegro aims at very low tariff protection, unlike Serbia, which wants to rely on a certain level of protectionism for a longer period of time. This disagreement is the major stumbling block standing in the way of the harmonization of their economic systems, which is a precondition for negotiations with the EU on the Stabilization and Association Agreement. Both reform strategies have led to a disappointing supply-side response. Serbia has entered into what appears as a transitional recession, at least when it comes to growth of industry, while Montenegro is stagnating at best. In addition, macroeconomic disequilibria - external, fiscal and labour market imbalances - are increasing. Those coincide with the decrease of foreign financial support and investment; and also with the prolongation of the prospects for EU accession despite the promises given at the EU-Western Balkans summit in Thessaloniki held at the end of June 2003. After the initial strong response by the government to the assassination of the Serbian prime minister Zoran Djindjic, the anti-organized-crime campaign is losing its momentum. With that, political instability is increasing. Some of it is due to the approach After the initial strong response by the government to the assassination of the Serbian prime minister Zoran Djindjic, the anti-organized-crime campaign is losing its momentum. With that, political instability is increasing. Some of it is due to the approaching elections, with early elections possible in autumn 2003 or regular elections in autumn 2004 at the latest. The recent conflict between the ministry of finance and the central bank in Serbia should be seen in that light. These conflicts are bound to escalate as the elections come closer in time. The current economic developments are not sustainable, especially in Serbia. Changes in the economic policy can be expected to turn around the negative trends in Serbia. Those are seen as necessary by the governing coalition which wants to stay in power after the elections. Thus, some relaxation of the monetary policy can be expected with the change in the central bank of Serbia. In Montenegro, due to the use of the euro and the need to continue with the fiscal consolidation, there is no room for a policy change and thus for short-term recovery. The crisis in Serbia cannot be overcome without democratization. That means elections. It is, however, not to be expected that one round of elections will bring speedy improvement. It will probably take another round for political stability to be achieved and economic development to be put on a sustainable path. Similar political developments should be expected in Montenegro too.

Suggested Citation

  • Vladimir Gligorov, 2003. "Serbia and Montenegro: Transition with Organized Crime," wiiw Country Profile 19, The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies, wiiw.
  • Handle: RePEc:wii:cprofi:19
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://wiiw.ac.at/serbia-and-montenegro-transition-with-organized-crime-dlp-11.pdf
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Vladimir Gligorov & Mario Holzner & Michael A Landesmann, 2004. "Prospects for Further (South-) Eastern EU Enlargement: From Divergence to Convergence?," Palgrave Macmillan Books, in: Michael A Landesmann & Dariusz K Rosati (ed.), Shaping the New Europe, chapter 12, pages 315-345, Palgrave Macmillan.
    2. Gérard Roland, 2004. "Transition and Economics: Politics, Markets, and Firms," MIT Press Books, The MIT Press, edition 1, volume 1, number 026268148x, April.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Eicher, Theo S. & Schreiber, Till, 2010. "Structural policies and growth: Time series evidence from a natural experiment," Journal of Development Economics, Elsevier, vol. 91(1), pages 169-179, January.
    2. Rode, Martin & Gwartney, James D., 2012. "Does democratization facilitate economic liberalization?," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 28(4), pages 607-619.
    3. Lamo, Ana & Messina, Julián & Wasmer, Etienne, 2011. "Are specific skills an obstacle to labor market adjustment?," Labour Economics, Elsevier, vol. 18(2), pages 240-256, April.
    4. Simeon Djankov & Edward Miguel & Yingyi Qian & Gérard Roland & Ekaterina Zhuravskaya, 2005. "Who are Russia's Entrepreneurs?," Journal of the European Economic Association, MIT Press, vol. 3(2-3), pages 587-597, 04/05.
    5. Pavel Ciaian & Ján Pokrivčák & Dušan Drabik, 2008. "Prečo sú niektoré sektory v tranzitívnych ekonomikách menej reformované ako ostatné? prípad výskumu a vzdelávania v oblasti ekonómie [Why some sectors of transition economies are less reformed than," Politická ekonomie, Prague University of Economics and Business, vol. 2008(6), pages 819-836.
    6. Gersbach, Hans & Jackson, Matthew O. & Muller, Philippe & Tejada, Oriol, 2023. "Electoral competition with costly policy changes: A dynamic perspective," Journal of Economic Theory, Elsevier, vol. 214(C).
    7. Masten, Arjana Brezigar & Coricelli, Fabrizio & Masten, Igor, 2008. "Non-linear growth effects of financial development: Does financial integration matter?," Journal of International Money and Finance, Elsevier, vol. 27(2), pages 295-313, March.
    8. Grzegorz W. Kolodko, 2009. "A Two-thirds Rate of Success: Polish Transformation and Economic Development, 1989-2008," WIDER Working Paper Series RP2009-14, World Institute for Development Economic Research (UNU-WIDER).
    9. repec:wvu:wpaper:06-03 is not listed on IDEAS
    10. DELL'ANNO, Roberto & VILLA, Stefania, 2012. "Growth in Transition Countries: Big Bang versus Gradualism," CELPE Discussion Papers 122, CELPE - CEnter for Labor and Political Economics, University of Salerno, Italy.
    11. Grigoriadis, Theocharis, 2017. "Religion, administration & public goods: Experimental evidence from Russia," Economic Modelling, Elsevier, vol. 66(C), pages 42-60.
    12. Grajzl, Peter & Baniak, Andrzej, 2018. "Private enforcement, corruption, and antitrust design," Journal of Comparative Economics, Elsevier, vol. 46(1), pages 284-307.
    13. Mübariz Hasanov & Tolga Omay, 2011. "The Relationship Between Inflation, Output Growth, and Their Uncertainties: Evidence from Selected CEE Countries," Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 47(0), pages 5-20, July.
    14. Campos, Nauro F & Giovannoni, Francesco, 2006. "The Determinants of Asset Stripping: Theory and Evidence from the Transition Economies," Journal of Law and Economics, University of Chicago Press, vol. 49(2), pages 681-706, October.
    15. Kryeziu Liridon & Coşkun Recai, 2018. "Political and Economic Institutions and Economic Performance: Evidence from Kosovo," South East European Journal of Economics and Business, Sciendo, vol. 13(2), pages 84-99, December.
    16. Mark Gradstein & Branko Milanovic, 2004. "Does Libertè = Egalité? A Survey of the Empirical Links between Democracy and Inequality with Some Evidence on the Transition Economies," Journal of Economic Surveys, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 18(4), pages 515-537, September.
    17. Nandini Gupta & John C. Ham & Jan Svejnar, 2000. "Priorities and Sequencing in Privatization: Theory and Evidence from the Czech Republic," William Davidson Institute Working Papers Series 323, William Davidson Institute at the University of Michigan.
    18. Johan F. M. Swinnen & Liesbeth Dries & Karen Macours, 2005. "Transition and agricultural labor," Agricultural Economics, International Association of Agricultural Economists, vol. 32(1), pages 15-34, January.
    19. Ethan Ligon & Laura Schechter, 2003. "Measuring Vulnerability," Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, vol. 113(486), pages 95-102, March.
    20. Xiwei Zhu & Ye Liu & Ming He & Deming Luo & Yiyun Wu, 2019. "Entrepreneurship and industrial clusters: evidence from China industrial census," Small Business Economics, Springer, vol. 52(3), pages 595-616, March.
    21. Fidrmuc, Jana P. & Fidrmuc, Jan, 2006. "Can you teach old dogs new tricks? On complementarity of human capital and incentives," Journal of International Money and Finance, Elsevier, vol. 25(3), pages 445-458, April.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    Serbia and Montenegro; transition; macroeconomic stability; organized crime;
    All these keywords.

    JEL classification:

    • P26 - Political Economy and Comparative Economic Systems - - Socialist and Transition Economies - - - Property Rights
    • P30 - Political Economy and Comparative Economic Systems - - Socialist Institutions and Their Transitions - - - General
    • P35 - Political Economy and Comparative Economic Systems - - Socialist Institutions and Their Transitions - - - Public Finance

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:wii:cprofi:19. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Customer service (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/wiiwwat.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.