IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/mon/ceddtr/30.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Comportement humain et rationalités dans les pays en développement

Author

Listed:
  • Stéphane Meignel

    (Groupe d'Economie du Développement Université Montesquieu Bordeaux IV)

Abstract

The application of marginalist instruments for understanding the behaviour of Southern individuals has always met numerous oppositions. According to them, the rationality claimed by the neo_classical theory is not convenient for studying these non_western societies and the underlying psychological hypothesis (homo oeconomicus) is completely unsuitable for explaining individual motivations. The present article proposes to examine these two criticisms. First of all, reviewing the definition of rationality, we underscore the existence of two very different definitions of "rationality",applying not at all to the same field of research. One generic (formal) definition of rationality which is "philosophically and psychologically neutral" [Malinvaud], expressing merely a certain coherence of choice. Following in Sen's footsteps, we illustrate moreover that this coherence of choices is very little constraining insofar as it is not verifiable. However marginalist analysis provides also definitions of rationality which are more concrete (substantial). They definitely ascribe a very restrictive vision to human motivation, one of them being the famous homo oeconomicus. The non_psychological dimension of rational choice (formal definition) is dedicated to the study of social interaction, whereas the psychological dimension of rational choice (substantial definition) focuses on the individuals'motivation, on what makes them act. These two levels of analysis are therefore radically different, but they are often confused.This confusion explains why many economist are getting into psychology without noticing it...Secondly, we show that the restrictive image of the homo oeconomicus still has a great explanatory fertility for conveying the choices of Southern individuals. One therefore has to adapt the satellite hypothesis of our models and envisage with more attention the context in which individuals make their decisions. By taking into account certain important characteristics of the external environment of developing contries, namely the very imperfect functioning of the markets, this approach makes it possible to discover the subtle forms taken on by the economic motives of Southern individuals. Despites the fact that the complexity and the specificity of traditional societies disturb the perception of elementary economic stakes, this approach has an undeniable explanatory power. (Full text in French)

Suggested Citation

  • Stéphane Meignel, 1998. "Comportement humain et rationalités dans les pays en développement," Documents de travail 30, Groupe d'Economie du Développement de l'Université Montesquieu Bordeaux IV.
  • Handle: RePEc:mon:ceddtr:30
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    To our knowledge, this item is not available for download. To find whether it is available, there are three options:
    1. Check below whether another version of this item is available online.
    2. Check on the provider's web page whether it is in fact available.
    3. Perform a search for a similarly titled item that would be available.

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Jean-Marc Fontaine & Alice Sindzingre, 1991. "Macro-Micro Linkages: Structural Adjustment and Fertilizer Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa," OECD Development Centre Working Papers 49, OECD Publishing.
    2. Hirshleifer, Jack, 1985. "The Expanding Domain of Economics," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 75(6), pages 53-68, December.
    3. Amartya K. Sen, 1966. "Peasants and Dualism with or without Surplus Labor," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 74(5), pages 425-425.
    4. Ball, Richard & Pounder, Laurie, 1996. ""Efficient but Poor" Revisited," Economic Development and Cultural Change, University of Chicago Press, vol. 44(4), pages 735-760, July.
    5. Roger Frydman, 1994. "Sur l'opposition de la rationalité substantive et de la rationalité procédurale," Cahiers d'Économie Politique, Programme National Persée, vol. 24(1), pages 167-177.
    6. V. M. Dandekar, 1962. "Economic Theory And Agrarian Reform," Oxford Economic Papers, Oxford University Press, vol. 14(1), pages 69-80.
    7. Shira B. Lewin, 1996. "Economics and Psychology: Lessons for Our Own Day from the Early Twentieth Century," Journal of Economic Literature, American Economic Association, vol. 34(3), pages 1293-1323, September.
    8. Jayne, T S, 1994. "Do High Food Marketing Costs Constrain Cash Crop Production? Evidence from Zimbabwe," Economic Development and Cultural Change, University of Chicago Press, vol. 42(2), pages 387-402, January.
    9. repec:bla:econom:v:40:y:1973:i:159:p:241-59 is not listed on IDEAS
    10. Taladidia Thiombiano, 1997. "La controverse empirique et théorique posée par le comportement des producteurs-consommateurs," Revue Tiers Monde, Programme National Persée, vol. 38(152), pages 821-836.
    11. Sen, Amartya, 1993. "Internal Consistency of Choice," Econometrica, Econometric Society, vol. 61(3), pages 495-521, May.
    12. Catherine Quinet, 1994. "Herbert Simon et la rationalité," Revue Française d'Économie, Programme National Persée, vol. 9(1), pages 133-181.
    13. Adams, John, 1986. "Peasant rationality: Individuals, groups, cultures," World Development, Elsevier, vol. 14(2), pages 273-282, February.
    14. Carlo Benetti & Jean Cartelier, 1994. "L'intérêt limité de l'hypothèse de rationalité individuelle," Cahiers d'Économie Politique, Programme National Persée, vol. 24(1), pages 19-35.
    15. Stigler, George J & Becker, Gary S, 1977. "De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 67(2), pages 76-90, March.
    16. George Dalton, 1962. "Traditional Production in Primitive African Economies," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 76(3), pages 360-378.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Romaniuc, Rustam, 2017. "Intrinsic motivation in economics: A history," Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics (formerly The Journal of Socio-Economics), Elsevier, vol. 67(C), pages 56-64.
    2. Ole Røgeberg & Morten Nordberg, 2005. "A defence of absurd theories in economics," Journal of Economic Methodology, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 12(4), pages 543-562.
    3. Licht Amir N., 2008. "Social Norms and the Law: Why Peoples Obey the Law," Review of Law & Economics, De Gruyter, vol. 4(3), pages 715-750, December.
    4. Bruno Frey, 1999. "State Support and Creativity in the Arts: Some New Considerations," Journal of Cultural Economics, Springer;The Association for Cultural Economics International, vol. 23(1), pages 71-85, March.
    5. Cheng Li, 2019. "Morality and value neutrality in economics: a dualist view," The Journal of Philosophical Economics, Bucharest Academy of Economic Studies, The Journal of Philosophical Economics, vol. 12(2), pages 97-118, May.
    6. Jimena Hurtado, 2005. "The Utilitarian Foundations Of The Economic Approach To Human Behavior," Documentos CEDE 3633, Universidad de los Andes, Facultad de Economía, CEDE.
    7. Bruno S. Frey & Matthias Benz, 2004. "From Imperialism to Inspiration: A Survey of Economics and Psychology," Chapters, in: John B. Davis & Alain Marciano & Jochen Runde (ed.), The Elgar Companion To Economics and Philosophy, chapter 4, Edward Elgar Publishing.
    8. Félix-Fernando Muñoz & María-Isabel Encinar, 2019. "Some elements for a definition of an evolutionary efficiency criterion," Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Springer, vol. 29(3), pages 919-937, July.
    9. Cyril Hédoin, 2017. "Normative economics and paternalism: the problem with the preference-satisfaction account of welfare," Constitutional Political Economy, Springer, vol. 28(3), pages 286-310, September.
    10. Stavros A. Drakopoulos, 2020. "Pay Level Comparisons in Job Satisfaction Research and Mainstream Economic Methodology," Journal of Happiness Studies, Springer, vol. 21(3), pages 825-842, March.
    11. Amavilah, Voxi Heinrich, 2018. "Endogenous constraints, coefficients of economic distance, and economic performance of African countries – An exploratory essay," MPRA Paper 90065, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    12. Margit Osterloh, 2007. "Psychologische Ökonomik: Integration statt Konfrontation," Schmalenbach Journal of Business Research, Springer, vol. 59(56), pages 82-111, January.
    13. S. Abu Turab Rizvi, 2001. "Preference Formation and the Axioms of Choice," Review of Political Economy, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 13(2), pages 141-159.
    14. Sauer, J. & Mendoza-Escalante, A., 2008. "Farming in the Eastern Amazon – Poor but Allocatively Efficient," Proceedings “Schriften der Gesellschaft für Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften des Landbaues e.V.”, German Association of Agricultural Economists (GEWISOLA), vol. 43, March.
    15. Stavros, Drakopoulos, 2021. "The Relation of Neoclassical Economics to other Disciplines: The case of Physics and Psychology," MPRA Paper 106597, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    16. Broussolle, Damien, 2005. "Internal consistency of choice, Sen and the spirit of revealed preferences: A behaviorist approach," Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics (formerly The Journal of Socio-Economics), Elsevier, vol. 34(5), pages 605-620, October.
    17. van den Bergh, Jeroen C. J. M. & Ferrer-i-Carbonell, Ada & Munda, Giuseppe, 2000. "Alternative models of individual behaviour and implications for environmental policy," Ecological Economics, Elsevier, vol. 32(1), pages 43-61, January.
    18. Elias Khalil, 2006. "Moral Outrage," Monash Economics Working Papers 07/06, Monash University, Department of Economics.
    19. Ebert Udo & Hagen Oskar von dem, 2002. "Exogenous Preferences, and Endogenous Tastes / Exogene Präferenzen und endogener Geschmack," Journal of Economics and Statistics (Jahrbuecher fuer Nationaloekonomie und Statistik), De Gruyter, vol. 222(5), pages 513-530, October.
    20. Angela C. M. de Oliveira & Catherine Eckel & Rachel T. A. Croson, 2012. "The Stability of Social Preferences in a Low‐Income Neighborhood," Southern Economic Journal, John Wiley & Sons, vol. 79(1), pages 15-45, July.

    More about this item

    JEL classification:

    • O00 - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth - - General - - - General
    • B4 - Schools of Economic Thought and Methodology - - Economic Methodology
    • P46 - Political Economy and Comparative Economic Systems - - Other Economic Systems - - - Consumer Economics; Health; Education and Training; Welfare, Income, Wealth, and Poverty

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:mon:ceddtr:30. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: the person in charge (email available below). General contact details of provider: .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.