IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/hal/wpaper/halshs-00587708.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

La connexion des réseaux comme facteur de changement institutionnel : l'exemple des vins de Bourgogne

Author

Listed:
  • Robert Boyer

    (PSE - Paris School of Economics - UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne - ENS-PSL - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris Sciences et Lettres - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement, PJSE - Paris-Jourdan Sciences Economiques - ENS-PSL - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris Sciences et Lettres - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique)

  • Denis Boyer

    (Instituto de Fisica - Universidad National Autonoma de Mexico)

  • Gilles Laferté

    (Unité MIAJ - INRA - Mathématiques et Informatique Appliquées - INRA - Institut National de la Recherche Agronomique)

Abstract

How to explain the change that occurred in the inter-war period in the assessment of Burgundy wines quality? A previous historical and ethnological study has analyzed the shift from the domination of the wine market by the traders of Beaune to the vineyard owners around Dijon. This research proposes some tools and a basic formalization in order to account of this structural transformation. A first analysis in terms of networks emphasizes that the change observed in the economic field in favour of the owners could not have taken place without the superposition of their influence in the cultural and political fields, both at the national and regional levels. Thus some actors are quite central, in the linking of different networks and the shift from one standard to another in the evaluation of wine quality. Consequently the economic equilibrium itself is drastically altered. This supports a theory of power in terms of structural holes "à la Burt". The tools of statistical physics are then adapted to this socio-economic context in order to get a formal dynamic model. It shows that long distance links from Dijon to Paris makes possible to overcome the initial asymmetry in favour of the Beaune traders. Modelling also suggests that this influence is not monotonous since there is a threshold for the probability of a long distance interaction above which prevails again a symmetrical equilibrium between Beaune and Dijon. Lastly, the same structural model can be applied mutatis mutandis to the current crisis of some French vintages: the internationalization of another quality standard for wines is the consequence of the emergence of new consumer countries. Thus, these three analyses converge towards the same provisional conclusion: the stability of local interactions leading to a set of conventions and institutions can be challenged by the strategy of new actors that benefit from long distance links and their ability to connect economic along with cultural or political networks.

Suggested Citation

  • Robert Boyer & Denis Boyer & Gilles Laferté, 2007. "La connexion des réseaux comme facteur de changement institutionnel : l'exemple des vins de Bourgogne," Working Papers halshs-00587708, HAL.
  • Handle: RePEc:hal:wpaper:halshs-00587708
    Note: View the original document on HAL open archive server: https://shs.hal.science/halshs-00587708
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://shs.hal.science/halshs-00587708/document
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. David, Paul A, 1985. "Clio and the Economics of QWERTY," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 75(2), pages 332-337, May.
    2. A. Barrat & M. Weigt, 2000. "On the properties of small-world network models," The European Physical Journal B: Condensed Matter and Complex Systems, Springer;EDP Sciences, vol. 13(3), pages 547-560, February.
    3. Steven H. Strogatz, 2001. "Exploring complex networks," Nature, Nature, vol. 410(6825), pages 268-276, March.
    4. Guillaume Deffuant & David Neau & Frederic Amblard & Gérard Weisbuch, 2000. "Mixing beliefs among interacting agents," Advances in Complex Systems (ACS), World Scientific Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd., vol. 3(01n04), pages 87-98.
    5. M. Wołoszyn & D. Stauffer & K. Kułakowski, 2007. "Order-disorder phase transition in a cliquey social network," The European Physical Journal B: Condensed Matter and Complex Systems, Springer;EDP Sciences, vol. 57(3), pages 331-335, June.
    6. S. Gil & D. H. Zanette, 2005. "Optimal disorder for segregation in annealed small worlds," The European Physical Journal B: Condensed Matter and Complex Systems, Springer;EDP Sciences, vol. 47(2), pages 265-273, September.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Robert Boyer & Denis Boyer & Gilles Laferté, 2007. "La connexion des réseaux comme facteur de changement institutionnel : l'exemple des vins de Bourgogne," PSE Working Papers halshs-00587708, HAL.
    2. María Cecilia Gimenez & Luis Reinaudi & Ana Pamela Paz-García & Paulo Marcelo Centres & Antonio José Ramirez-Pastor, 2021. "Opinion evolution in the presence of constant propaganda: homogeneous and localized cases," The European Physical Journal B: Condensed Matter and Complex Systems, Springer;EDP Sciences, vol. 94(1), pages 1-11, January.
    3. Lawford, Steve & Mehmeti, Yll, 2020. "Cliques and a new measure of clustering: With application to U.S. domestic airlines," Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, Elsevier, vol. 560(C).
    4. Floortje Alkemade & Carolina Castaldi, 2005. "Strategies for the Diffusion of Innovations on Social Networks," Computational Economics, Springer;Society for Computational Economics, vol. 25(1), pages 3-23, February.
    5. Marr, Carsten & Hütt, Marc-Thorsten, 2005. "Topology regulates pattern formation capacity of binary cellular automata on graphs," Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, Elsevier, vol. 354(C), pages 641-662.
    6. Bombelli, Alessandro & Santos, Bruno F. & Tavasszy, Lóránt, 2020. "Analysis of the air cargo transport network using a complex network theory perspective," Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, Elsevier, vol. 138(C).
    7. Li, Chunguang, 2009. "Memorizing morph patterns in small-world neuronal network," Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, Elsevier, vol. 388(2), pages 240-246.
    8. Jeho Lee & Jaeyong Song & Jae-Suk Yang, 2016. "Network structure effects on incumbency advantage," Strategic Management Journal, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 37(8), pages 1632-1648, August.
    9. Wiebke Roß & Jens Weghake, 2018. "Wa(h)re Liebe: Was Online-Dating-Plattformen über zweiseitige Märkte lehren," TUC Working Papers in Economics 0017, Abteilung für Volkswirtschaftslehre, Technische Universität Clausthal (Department of Economics, Technical University Clausthal).
    10. Marta Gancarczyk, 2010. "Model schyłku i odrodzenia klastrów," Gospodarka Narodowa. The Polish Journal of Economics, Warsaw School of Economics, issue 3, pages 1-21.
    11. Narduzzo, Alessandro & Warglien, Massimo, 1996. "Learning from the Experience of Others: An Experiment on Information Contagion," Industrial and Corporate Change, Oxford University Press and the Associazione ICC, vol. 5(1), pages 113-126.
    12. John S. Earle & Klara Z. Sabirianova, 2002. "How Late to Pay? Understanding Wage Arrears in Russia," Journal of Labor Economics, University of Chicago Press, vol. 20(3), pages 661-707, July.
    13. Rehák Štefan & Hudec Oto & Buček Milan, 2013. "Path dependency and path plasticity in emerging industries: Two cases from Slovakia," ZFW – Advances in Economic Geography, De Gruyter, vol. 57(1-2), pages 52-66, October.
    14. Beomjin Choi & T. S. Raghu & Ajay Vinzé & Kevin J. Dooley, 2019. "Effectiveness of standards consortia: Social network perspectives," Information Systems Frontiers, Springer, vol. 21(2), pages 405-416, April.
    15. Mahzouni, Arian, 2019. "The role of institutional entrepreneurship in emerging energy communities: The town of St. Peter in Germany," Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, Elsevier, vol. 107(C), pages 297-308.
    16. Sven Banisch & Eckehard Olbrich, 2021. "An Argument Communication Model of Polarization and Ideological Alignment," Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, vol. 24(1), pages 1-1.
    17. Emerson, Isaac Arnold & Amala, Arumugam, 2017. "Protein contact maps: A binary depiction of protein 3D structures," Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, Elsevier, vol. 465(C), pages 782-791.
    18. Georg Erber, 1994. "Verdoorn's or Okun's Law?: Employment and Growth Experiences in OECD Countries, 1960-1993," Discussion Papers of DIW Berlin 98, DIW Berlin, German Institute for Economic Research.
    19. Atallah, Shadi S. & Huang, Ju-Chin & Leahy, Jessica & Bennett, Karen, 2020. "Preference Heterogeneity and Neighborhood Effect in Invasive Species Control: The Case of Glossy Buckthorn in New Hampshire and Maine Forests," 2020 Annual Meeting, July 26-28, Kansas City, Missouri 304623, Agricultural and Applied Economics Association.
    20. McCloskey Deirdre Nansen, 2018. "The Two Movements in Economic Thought, 1700–2000: Empty Economic Boxes Revisited," Man and the Economy, De Gruyter, vol. 5(2), pages 1-20, December.

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:hal:wpaper:halshs-00587708. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: CCSD (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/ .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.