IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/taf/ufajxx/v67y2011i4p42-49.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Diversification Return, Portfolio Rebalancing, and the Commodity Return Puzzle

Author

Listed:
  • Scott Willenbrock

Abstract

Diversification return is an incremental return earned by a rebalanced portfolio of assets. The author argues that the underlying source of the diversification return is the rebalancing; in contrast, the incremental return of a buy-and-hold portfolio is driven by the fact that the best-performing assets become a greater fraction of the portfolio. On the basis of these findings, the author resolves two aspects of a puzzle associated with Gorton and Rouwenhorst’s index of commodity futures.The term diversification return was coined in the context of a rebalanced portfolio—that is, a portfolio with a constant percentage invested in each asset. The contribution of each asset to the portfolio’s compound return, dubbed the return contribution, exceeds the asset’s compound return by an incremental amount called the diversification return. The portfolio’s diversification return is the weighted average of the assets’ diversification returns.One is led to wonder whether the diversification return has two separate, perhaps related, aspects: diversification and rebalancing. Several authors have argued in favor of this point of view to various degrees. For example, some have regarded a portfolio’s diversification return as the difference between its geometric average return and the (weighted) geometric average returns of its individual assets, regardless of whether the weights are constant.In this article, I revisited the issue of diversification return and portfolio rebalancing. I showed that diversification return can be precisely defined in the context of a rebalanced portfolio. I argued that the reduction in variance inherent in a diversified portfolio is a necessary, but not sufficient, condition to earning a diversification return.I clarified the underlying source of diversification return. The diversification return is usually expressed in terms of the difference between the variance of an asset and its covariance with the portfolio. Although this approach is elegant and useful, it masks the fact that the diversification return stems from selling assets that have appreciated in relative value and buying assets that have declined in relative value, as measured by their weights in the portfolio.I also analyzed a buy-and-hold portfolio. Although such a portfolio can have no diversification return, it can have an incremental return relative to the initially weighted average of the compound returns of the assets. This result stems from the fact that, over time, a buy-and-hold portfolio will increase the weights of the best-performing assets. This result, however, also changes the risk profile of the portfolio. In contrast, an investor earns a diversification return in a rebalanced portfolio while maintaining a constant risk profile.Finally, I used these results to resolve two aspects of the commodity return puzzle. I argued that the excess return (above the risk-free rate) of a commodity futures index, which is rebalanced monthly, can be largely accounted for by the diversification return. If the index is not rebalanced, however, it generates a significant incremental excess return as a buy-and-hold portfolio because the compound returns of the underlying commodity futures in the index have a wide range of values. Thus, no contradiction exists; the commodity futures index generates an excess return in both its rebalanced and unrebalanced incarnations but for totally different and unrelated reasons.

Suggested Citation

  • Scott Willenbrock, 2011. "Diversification Return, Portfolio Rebalancing, and the Commodity Return Puzzle," Financial Analysts Journal, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 67(4), pages 42-49, July.
  • Handle: RePEc:taf:ufajxx:v:67:y:2011:i:4:p:42-49
    DOI: 10.2469/faj.v67.n4.1
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://hdl.handle.net/10.2469/faj.v67.n4.1
    Download Restriction: Access to full text is restricted to subscribers.

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.2469/faj.v67.n4.1?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:taf:ufajxx:v:67:y:2011:i:4:p:42-49. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Chris Longhurst (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.tandfonline.com/ufaj20 .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.