IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/sae/ratsoc/v9y1997i2p131-161.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Appearances Can Be Deceptive

Author

Listed:
  • Scott Sigmund Gartner
  • Gary M. Segura

Abstract

This paper focuses on two neglected facets of political mobilization among members of repressed social groups: some people pay costs for membership in advance of any political activity; and external recognition of an individual as a group member is uncertain. Using these propositions, we create a rational choice, decision-theoretic model of the choices to identify and mobilize with three major implications. First, we should expect to observe a higher degree of mobilization from the self-identified members of invisible groups, such as atheists and gays, than from the entire population of visible groups, such as women and racial minorities. But, this apparent higher level of mobilization is an artifact of a self-selection process; when comparing true total group populations, invisible group members actually mobilize at lower rates. This result addresses the apparent problem that, frequently, more people appear to be politically active than would be expected from collective action theorists' `five percent Rule'. Second, most attempts to root out and repress invisible groups are likely to lead to greater mobilization by members. Third, visible groups are more likely to receive support from non-group members than groups whose membership is unidentifiable, due to the likelihood and consequences of erroneous attribution of group membership to these allies.

Suggested Citation

  • Scott Sigmund Gartner & Gary M. Segura, 1997. "Appearances Can Be Deceptive," Rationality and Society, , vol. 9(2), pages 131-161, May.
  • Handle: RePEc:sae:ratsoc:v:9:y:1997:i:2:p:131-161
    DOI: 10.1177/104346397009002001
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1177/104346397009002001
    Download Restriction: no

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1177/104346397009002001?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Bradford Cornell, 1995. "A Hypothesis Regarding the Origins of Ethnic Discrimination," Rationality and Society, , vol. 7(1), pages 4-30, January.
    2. Wendt, Alexander, 1994. "Collective Identity Formation and the International State," American Political Science Review, Cambridge University Press, vol. 88(2), pages 384-396, June.
    3. Bradford Cornell, 1995. "A Hypothesis Regarding the Origins of Ethnic Discrimination," Rationality and Society, , vol. 7(4), pages 491-493, October.
    4. Mitra, Subrata K., 1995. "The Rational Politics of Cultural Nationalism: Subnational Movements of South Asia in Comparative Perspective," British Journal of Political Science, Cambridge University Press, vol. 25(1), pages 57-77, January.
    5. Bobo, Lawrence & Gilliam, Franklin D., 1990. "Race, Sociopolitical Participation, and Black Empowerment," American Political Science Review, Cambridge University Press, vol. 84(2), pages 377-393, June.
    6. Johnson, Paul E., 1990. "Asymmetries in political entry," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 6(3), pages 377-396, December.
    7. Cornell, Bradford, 1995. "An Hypothesis Regarding the Origins of Ethnic Discrimination," Mathematical Social Sciences, Elsevier, vol. 30(1), pages 100-100, August.
    8. Kuran, Timur, 1990. "Private and Public Preferences," Economics and Philosophy, Cambridge University Press, vol. 6(1), pages 1-26, April.
    9. Nelson, Dale C., 1979. "Ethnicity and Socioeconomic Status as Sources of Participation: The Case for Ethnic Political Culture," American Political Science Review, Cambridge University Press, vol. 73(4), pages 1024-1038, December.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Arieh Gavious & Shlomo Mizrahi, 1999. "Two-Level Collective Action and Group Identity," Journal of Theoretical Politics, , vol. 11(4), pages 497-517, October.
    2. Murat Somer, 2001. "Cascades of Ethnic Polarization: Lessons from Yugoslavia," The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, , vol. 573(1), pages 127-151, January.
    3. Michael Hechter, 1995. "Comment on Cornell," Rationality and Society, , vol. 7(4), pages 489-491, October.
    4. Thomas Wagner, 1998. "Reciprocity And Efficiency," Rationality and Society, , vol. 10(3), pages 347-375, August.
    5. Adler, Emanuel & Crawford, Beverly, 2004. "Normative Power: The European Practice of Region Building and the Case of the Euro-Mediterranean Partnership (EMP)," Institute of European Studies, Working Paper Series qt6xx6n5p4, Institute of European Studies, UC Berkeley.
    6. Andreas Peichl & Nico Pestel & Sebastian Siegloch, 2013. "The politicians’ wage gap: insights from German members of parliament," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 156(3), pages 653-676, September.
    7. Woll, Cornelia, 2005. "Learning to Act on World Trade: Preference Formation of Large Firms in the United States and the European Union," MPIfG Discussion Paper 05/1, Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies.
    8. Brian Lai & Vanessa A. Lefler, 2017. "Examining the role of region and elections on representation in the UN Security Council," The Review of International Organizations, Springer, vol. 12(4), pages 585-611, December.
    9. Merran Hulse, 2014. "Actorness beyond the European Union: Comparing the International Trade Actorness of SADC and ECOWAS," Journal of Common Market Studies, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 52(3), pages 547-565, May.
    10. Robert Smith, 1996. "Social structure and voting choice: hypotheses, findings, and interpretations," Quality & Quantity: International Journal of Methodology, Springer, vol. 30(2), pages 137-160, May.
    11. Johansson-Stenman, Olof & Martinsson, Peter, 2006. "Honestly, why are you driving a BMW?," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Elsevier, vol. 60(2), pages 129-146, June.
    12. Brian Lai & Dan Reiter, 2000. "Democracy, Political Similarity, and International Alliances, 1816-1992," Journal of Conflict Resolution, Peace Science Society (International), vol. 44(2), pages 203-227, April.
    13. Tom W. Smith & Jibum Kim, 2013. "An Assessment of the Multi-level Integrated Database Approach," The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, , vol. 645(1), pages 185-221, January.
    14. Stephen Kinsella, 2009. "Preference Falsification in Teaching," Econ Journal Watch, Econ Journal Watch, vol. 6(3), pages 352-358, September.
    15. Johannes Urpelainen, 2011. "Domestic reform as a rationale for gradualism in international cooperation," Journal of Theoretical Politics, , vol. 23(3), pages 400-427, July.
    16. repec:spo:wpmain:info:hdl:2441/8529 is not listed on IDEAS
    17. Cornelia Woll, 2006. "The Road to External Representation: the European Commission's Activism in International Air Transport," SciencePo Working papers Main hal-01021127, HAL.
    18. Felix Oberholzer-Gee & Joel Waldfogel, 2001. "Electoral Acceleration: The Effect of Minority Population on Minority Voter Turnout," NBER Working Papers 8252, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    19. Petra Meier & Eline Severs, 2018. "The Dark Side of Descriptive Representation: Bodies, Normalisation and Exclusion," Politics and Governance, Cogitatio Press, vol. 6(3), pages 31-42.
    20. Timur Kuran, 1993. "The Unthinkable and the Unthought," Rationality and Society, , vol. 5(4), pages 473-505, October.
    21. François Facchini & Louis Jaeck, 2021. "Populism and the rational choice model: The case of the French National Front," Rationality and Society, , vol. 33(2), pages 196-228, May.

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:sae:ratsoc:v:9:y:1997:i:2:p:131-161. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: SAGE Publications (email available below). General contact details of provider: .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.