IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/prs/reveco/reco_0035-2764_1974_num_25_5_408172.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Coût et efficacité de l'impôt négatif

Author

Listed:
  • Lionel Stoléru

Abstract

[fre] L'objet de l'article est d'introduire une approche « coût-avantage » des différents barèmes de l'impôt négatif sur le revenu, pouvant être définis par un ou deux paramètres fondamentaux : le montant du revenu garanti G, le taux de l'impôt r, le seuil d'accès B. Du côté du coût, il apparaît que les modèles de distribution du revenu selon la taille de la famille peuvent être synthétisés par une seule fonction de coût S (B) ; S (B) est indépendante des paramètres du plan d'impôt négatif sur le revenu (I.N.) et donne le coût d'un «plan de base» permettant à chaque individu d'atteindre le niveau de revenu B. Alors, le coût de n'importe quel plan d'I.N. (r,B) est tout simplement r,S (B). Du côté des avantages, on introduit un concept d'efficacité en termes de pourcentage de la population restant au-dessous du seuil de pauvreté, après avoir bénéficié des aides. Si l'on cherche à rendre minimum ce pourcentage, on définit un optimum qui est habituellement un plan « équilibré » avec un taux d'impôt optimum variant de 0 à 100 %. La discussion des concepts d'optimum et d'efficacité conduit à la conclusion que l'analyse coût-avantage pourrait et devrait être appliquée à l'évaluation des plans de revenu garanti. [eng] Optimum negative income taxes. The purpose of the article is to introduce a " cost-benefit" approach of the alternative negative income tax schedules which can be defined by either 2 of 3 basic parameters : guarantee level G, tax rate r, break-even income B. On the cost side, it is shown that income-distribution patterns by family size can be synthetized ivithin a single cost function S (B) which is independent of the parameters of the negative income tax scheme and which gives the cost of the flat scheme bringing everybody to the B income level. Then, the cost of any N.I.T. scheme [r,B] is just r,S (B). On the benefit side, an efficiency concept is introduced in terms of the percentage of population which remains below the poverty Une after benefits. Minimizing this percentage defines an optimum which will usually be a "balanced " scheme with an optimum tax rate different from 0 or 100 percent. Discussion of the optimum and efficiency concepts leads to the conclusion that cosf~benefit analysis could and should be applied to assessment of income-maintenance schemes.

Suggested Citation

  • Lionel Stoléru, 1974. "Coût et efficacité de l'impôt négatif," Revue Économique, Programme National Persée, vol. 25(5), pages 745-761.
  • Handle: RePEc:prs:reveco:reco_0035-2764_1974_num_25_5_408172
    DOI: 10.3406/reco.1974.408172
    Note: DOI:10.3406/reco.1974.408172
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://doi.org/10.3406/reco.1974.408172
    Download Restriction: Data and metadata provided by Persée are licensed under a Creative Commons "Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0" License http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/3.0/

    File URL: https://www.persee.fr/doc/reco_0035-2764_1974_num_25_5_408172
    Download Restriction: Data and metadata provided by Persée are licensed under a Creative Commons "Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0" License http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/3.0/

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.3406/reco.1974.408172?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Zeckhauser, Richard J, 1971. "Optimal Mechanisms for Income Transfer," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 61(3), pages 324-334, June.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Christian Morrisson & Philippe Cazenave, 1973. "Fonctions d'utilité interdépendantes et théorie de la redistribution en économie de production," Revue Économique, Programme National Persée, vol. 24(5), pages 725-760.
    2. R. D. Husby, 1993. "The Minimum Wage, Wage Subsidies, And Poverty," Contemporary Economic Policy, Western Economic Association International, vol. 11(3), pages 30-38, July.
    3. Moffitt, Robert A., 2002. "Welfare programs and labor supply," Handbook of Public Economics, in: A. J. Auerbach & M. Feldstein (ed.), Handbook of Public Economics, edition 1, volume 4, chapter 34, pages 2393-2430, Elsevier.
    4. Emmanuel Saez, 2002. "Optimal Income Transfer Programs: Intensive versus Extensive Labor Supply Responses," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 117(3), pages 1039-1073.
    5. Patricia Justino, 2004. "Redistribution, Inequality and Political Conflict," HiCN Working Papers 05, Households in Conflict Network.
    6. Casey Mulligan & Tomas Philipson, "undated". "Merit Motives and Government Intervention: Public Finance in Reverse," University of Chicago - Population Research Center 2000-03, Chicago - Population Research Center.
    7. Thomas D. Birch, 1987. "Basic Needs: Paternalistic Government Welfare Policy with Distortionary Taxation," Public Finance Review, , vol. 15(3), pages 298-321, July.
    8. Browning, Edgar K., 1995. "Effects of the Earned Income Tax Credit on Income and Welfare," National Tax Journal, National Tax Association;National Tax Journal, vol. 48(1), pages 23-43, March.
    9. James D. Rodgers, 1973. "Distributional Externalities and the Optimal Form of Income Transfers," Public Finance Review, , vol. 1(3), pages 266-299, July.
    10. Leonardo Bursztyn & Lucas C. Coffman, 2012. "The Schooling Decision: Family Preferences, Intergenerational Conflict, and Moral Hazard in the Brazilian Favelas," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 120(3), pages 359-397.
    11. Eitan Berglas, 1976. "Income Tax, Wage Tax, and Optimal Tax," Public Finance Review, , vol. 4(1), pages 3-15, January.
    12. Huizinga, H.P., 1996. "Unemployment Benefits and Redistributive Taxes in the Presence of Labor Quality Externalities," Other publications TiSEM 460a1387-fe15-4f62-b8a6-8, Tilburg University, School of Economics and Management.
    13. J. Giertz, 1982. "A limited defense of Pareto optimal redistribution," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 39(2), pages 277-282, January.
    14. Cassone, Alberto & Marchese, Carla, 2001. "Should the death tax die? And should it leave an inheritance?," POLIS Working Papers 22, Institute of Public Policy and Public Choice - POLIS.
    15. Arbex Marcelo & Mattos Enlinson & Trudeau Christian, 2012. "Poverty, Informality and the Optimal General Income Tax Policy," The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, De Gruyter, vol. 12(1), pages 1-22, July.
    16. Christopher B. Colburn, 1993. "Work Requirements and Income Transfers," Public Finance Review, , vol. 21(2), pages 141-162, April.
    17. Lisa A. Robinson & James K. Hammitt & Richard J. Zeckhauser, 2016. "Attention to Distribution in U.S. Regulatory Analyses," Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, vol. 10(2), pages 308-328.
    18. John F. Johnston, 1975. "Utility Interdependence and Redistribution: Methodological Implications for Welfare Economics and the Theory of the Public Household," Public Finance Review, , vol. 3(3), pages 195-228, July.
    19. Robert A. Moffitt, 2003. "The Temporary Assistance for Needy Families Program," NBER Chapters, in: Means-Tested Transfer Programs in the United States, pages 291-364, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
    20. K. W Kevin Hsu & C. C. Yang, 2008. "Political Economy And The Social Marginal Cost Of Public Funds: The Case Of The Meltzer‐Richard Economy," Economic Inquiry, Western Economic Association International, vol. 46(3), pages 401-410, July.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:prs:reveco:reco_0035-2764_1974_num_25_5_408172. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Equipe PERSEE (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://www.persee.fr/collection/reco .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.