IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/bpj/ordojb/v52y2001i1p131-154n10.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Der Richter als Institution einer spontanen Ordnung: Einige kritische Bemerkungen zu einer Zentralfigur in Hayeks Theorie der kulturellen Evolution

Author

Listed:
  • Okruch Stefan

Abstract

The judge plays an important role in Hayek’s theory of cultural evolution. He argues that the universal rules of just conduct could only evolve in legal systems in which it was the task of judges to “discover” the appropriate rules. This article scrutinizes Hayek’s optimistic view on the judicial “shaping of the rule”. It asks, whether the beneficial effects of judge made law are indeed as generally to be expected as Hayek presented it. The analysis follows Hayek’s own methodological guidelines, which are depicted at the beginning. The following portrayal of the theory of cultural evolution puts special emphasis on the judge’s contribution to legal development. Hayek’s theory in general has been criticized along two lines: on the one hand, it was argued that the processes and the criteria of selection remain vague. On the other hand, it was stressed that an evolutionary process can only be expected to lead to beneficial outcomes under certain conditions, which ought to be specified. I argue that also adjudication, seen as a mechanism in legal evolution, is not beneficial as such. As an example I present a part of German Competion Law. This example is chosen, because it is directly related to the spontaneous order of markets and because the statute only gives some guidelines for “fair” competition. Thus, like in common law systems, judge-made law is extremly important. This example can show that, in contrast to Hayek’s unconditional statement about judge-made law, adjudication can result in serious distortions of a spontaneous order. From the perspective of legal philosophy I argue, that Hayek rejects legal positivism only with respect to the legislator, in not accepting each formally correct enacted statute as law. Conceptualizing any formally correct judicial decision as a valuable contributions to cultural evolution, however, is only another kind of positivism. Finally, Jhering’s early contibution to a theory of legal evolution is presented as a promising approach that could complement Hayek’s theory of cultural evolution.

Suggested Citation

  • Okruch Stefan, 2001. "Der Richter als Institution einer spontanen Ordnung: Einige kritische Bemerkungen zu einer Zentralfigur in Hayeks Theorie der kulturellen Evolution," ORDO. Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, De Gruyter, vol. 52(1), pages 131-154, January.
  • Handle: RePEc:bpj:ordojb:v:52:y:2001:i:1:p:131-154:n:10
    DOI: 10.1515/ordo-2001-0110
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://doi.org/10.1515/ordo-2001-0110
    Download Restriction: For access to full text, subscription to the journal or payment for the individual article is required.

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1515/ordo-2001-0110?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Vanberg, Viktor, 1986. "Spontaneous Market Order and Social Rules," Economics and Philosophy, Cambridge University Press, vol. 2(1), pages 75-100, April.
    2. Voigt Stefan, 1991. "Die evolutionsorientierte Theorie der Verfassung – Bemerkungen zum Ansatz von Hayeks –," Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftspolitik, De Gruyter, vol. 40(1-3), pages 93-108, September.
    3. Robert Sugden, 1993. "Normative judgments and spontaneous order: The contractarian element in Hayek's thought," Constitutional Political Economy, Springer, vol. 4(3), pages 393-424, September.
    4. Vanberg, Viktor J., 1981. "Liberaler Evolutionismus oder vertragstheoretischer Konstitutionalismus?," Beiträge zur Ordnungstheorie und Ordnungspolitik, Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen;Walter Eucken Institut, Freiburg, Germany, edition 1, volume 80, number urn:isbn:9783163444119, December.
    5. repec:mhr:untord:urn:isbn:9783161457135 is not listed on IDEAS
    6. Scott Gordon, 1981. "The Political Economy of F. A. Hayek: Review Article," Canadian Journal of Economics, Canadian Economics Association, vol. 14(3), pages 470-487, August.
    7. Vanberg, Viktor J., 1994. "Kulturelle Evolution und die Gestaltung von Regeln," Beiträge zur Ordnungstheorie und Ordnungspolitik, Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen;Walter Eucken Institut, Freiburg, Germany, edition 1, volume 127, number urn:isbn:9783161462641, December.
    8. Hodgson, Geoffrey M., 1991. "Hayek's Theory of Cultural Evolution: An Evaluation in the Light of Vanberg's Critique," Economics and Philosophy, Cambridge University Press, vol. 7(1), pages 67-82, April.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Niclas Berggren, 2006. "Legal positivism and property rights: a critique of Hayek and Peczenik," Constitutional Political Economy, Springer, vol. 17(3), pages 217-235, September.

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. Agnès Festré & Pierre Garrouste, 2009. "The economic analysis of social norms: A reappraisal of Hayek’s legacy," The Review of Austrian Economics, Springer;Society for the Development of Austrian Economics, vol. 22(3), pages 259-279, September.
    2. Luciano Andreozzi, 2005. "Hayek Reads the Literature on the Emergence of Norms," Constitutional Political Economy, Springer, vol. 16(3), pages 227-247, September.
    3. Fiori Stefano, 2005. "The emergence of instructions : some open problems in Hayek's theory," CESMEP Working Papers 200504, University of Turin.
    4. Agnès Festré & Pierre Garrouste, 2008. "L’analyse économique des normes sociales : une réévaluation de l’héritage hayékien," Revue Française d'Économie, Programme National Persée, vol. 22(4), pages 103-137.
    5. Marciano, Alain, 2009. "Why Hayek is a Darwinian (after all)? Hayek and Darwin on social evolution," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Elsevier, vol. 71(1), pages 52-61, July.
    6. Niclas Berggren, 2009. "Choosing one’s own informal institutions: on Hayek’s critique of Keynes’s immoralism," Constitutional Political Economy, Springer, vol. 20(2), pages 139-159, June.
    7. Dang, Ai-Thu & Mangolte, Pierre-André, 2002. "Endogénéisation des règles sociales et évolutionnisme culturel chez Friedrich A. Hayek," L'Actualité Economique, Société Canadienne de Science Economique, vol. 78(3), pages 321-345, Septembre.
    8. Manfred Streit, 1993. "Cognition, competition, and catallaxy in memory of Friedrich August von Hayek," Constitutional Political Economy, Springer, vol. 4(2), pages 223-262, March.
    9. Dominik H. Enste, 2001. "Schattenwirtschaft und Schwarzarbeit – Eine wirtschafts‐ und gesellschaftspolitische Herausforderung," Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik, Verein für Socialpolitik, vol. 2(2), pages 229-244, May.
    10. Stefano Fiori, 2006. "The emergence of institutions in Hayek’s theory: two views or one?," Constitutional Political Economy, Springer, vol. 17(1), pages 49-61, March.
    11. Douglas Whitman, 1998. "Hayek contra Pangloss on Evolutionary Systems," Constitutional Political Economy, Springer, vol. 9(1), pages 45-66, March.
    12. Daumann Frank, 2001. "Die Rolle der Evolution in Hayeks Konzept freiheitssichernder Regeln," ORDO. Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, De Gruyter, vol. 52(1), pages 83-102, January.
    13. Angela Ambrosino & Paolo Silvestri, 2020. "Hodgson: An Institution Across Disciplinary Barriers," Annals of the Fondazione Luigi Einaudi. An Interdisciplinary Journal of Economics, History and Political Science, Fondazione Luigi Einaudi, Torino (Italy), vol. 54(2), pages 329-348, December.
    14. Streit Manfred E., 1999. "Rechtsordnung und Handelnsordnung," ORDO. Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, De Gruyter, vol. 50(1), pages 93-104, January.
    15. Jackson, William A., 1993. "Culture, Society and Economic Theory," EconStor Open Access Articles and Book Chapters, ZBW - Leibniz Information Centre for Economics, vol. 5(4), pages 453-469.
    16. Vlad Tarko, 2015. "The role of ideas in political economy," The Review of Austrian Economics, Springer;Society for the Development of Austrian Economics, vol. 28(1), pages 17-39, March.
    17. Alain Leroux, 1997. "L'évolutionnisme de Friedrich Hayek. Une double controverse révélatrice d'une double illusion," Revue Économique, Programme National Persée, vol. 48(3), pages 751-760.
    18. Athanassios Pitsoulis & Steffen Groß, 2015. "“The other side of the argument”: Isaiah Berlin versus F. A. von Hayek on liberty, public policies, and the market," Constitutional Political Economy, Springer, vol. 26(4), pages 475-494, December.
    19. Alain Marciano, 2007. "Hayek’s theory of social evolution in the light of Darwin’s Descent of Man," ICER Working Papers 04-2007, ICER - International Centre for Economic Research.
    20. Shinji Teraji, 2014. "On cognition and cultural evolution," Mind & Society: Cognitive Studies in Economics and Social Sciences, Springer;Fondazione Rosselli, vol. 13(2), pages 167-182, November.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:bpj:ordojb:v:52:y:2001:i:1:p:131-154:n:10. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Peter Golla (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://www.degruyter.com .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.