IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/p/red/sed018/349.html
   My bibliography  Save this paper

Training, Offshoring, and the Job Ladder

Author

Listed:
  • Nezih Guner

    (CEMFI)

  • Alessandro Ruggieri

    (Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona, Barcelona GSE)

  • James Tybout

    (Pennsylvania State University)

Abstract

Over the past 40 years, labor market conditions in the United States and elsewhere have rapidly evolved. Skill premiums have grown, jobs in the middle of the skill distribution have become relatively scarce, and job and worker turnover rates have declined. At the same time, the fraction of the population attending college has grown, much of the manufacturing work force has shifted into services, and on-the-job training times have increased for high-skill workers. This paper interprets these patterns through the lens of a dynamic structural model that explains workers' human capital accumulation and earnings trajectories over their life cycles. The basic idea is as follows. Before entering the labor market, high school graduates who differ in their ability (human capital) levels decide whether to attend college. After their schooling decisions, skilled (college educated) and unskilled workers enter into the labor market and match with firms that produce different tasks. Firms that produce the same task differ in their idiosyncratic productivity levels. Once employed, workers build human capital through experience, and may also invest in on-the-job training. Both types of human capital accumulation induce wage growth over their life cycles, and this growth is augmented by the arrival of job offers from "poaching" employers, which force firms to compete for their services. But their wages fall if product market shocks throw them into unemployment, interrupting their human capital accumulation and reducing their bargaining power with potential new employers. Tasks, which are produced by one worker-one pair firms are demanded by firms that produce differentiated consumption goods. Consumption good producers can obtain different tasks they need for production from domestic or foreign markets. Tasks differ extent to which they can be obtained from foreign markets. Offshoring, and import competition affect workers' careers through all of these mechanisms. While improving productive efficiency, these shocks destroy jobs in the trade-exposed occupations, change job offer arrival rates for each worker type, and change incentives to invest in college degrees. Also, by reducing the relative demand for mid-skill occupations, they affect workers' incentives to invest in on-the-job training.

Suggested Citation

  • Nezih Guner & Alessandro Ruggieri & James Tybout, 2018. "Training, Offshoring, and the Job Ladder," 2018 Meeting Papers 349, Society for Economic Dynamics.
  • Handle: RePEc:red:sed018:349
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://red-files-public.s3.amazonaws.com/meetpapers/2018/paper_349.pdf
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Rafael Dix-Carneiro & João Paulo Pessoa & Ricardo Reyes-Heroles & Sharon Traiberman, 2023. "Globalization, Trade Imbalances, and Labor Market Adjustment," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College, vol. 138(2), pages 1109-1171.
    2. Machin, Stephen & Costa, Rui & Dhingra, Swati, 2019. "Trade and Worker Deskilling," CEPR Discussion Papers 13768, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.
    3. Davidson, Carl & Heyman, Fredrik & Matusz, Steven & Sjöholm, Fredrik & Zhu, Susan Chun, 2020. "Globalization, the jobs ladder and economic mobility," European Economic Review, Elsevier, vol. 127(C).
    4. Davidson, Carl & Matusz, Steven & Chun Zhu, Susan & Heyman, Fredrik & Sjoholm, Fredrik, 2018. "Globalization and the Jobs Ladder," Working Papers 2018-8, Michigan State University, Department of Economics.

    More about this item

    NEP fields

    This paper has been announced in the following NEP Reports:

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:red:sed018:349. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Christian Zimmermann (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/sedddea.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.