Author
Abstract
[eng] Political economy of international financial architecture. . The objective of the new architecture of the international financial system is to master the international financial instability by improving the transparency and the supervision of markets, and by arousing a greatest sense of responsibility in the prevention and management of crises, of both private and public actors. But it is very improbable for the new architecture to take the form of rules of law whose combination would open on a new system forced upon the international community, to the image of the creation of the IMF in 1944. It is likely to be a pragmatic reply to the international financial instability rather than an institutional evolution of the modes of international monetary and financial governance. The ambition to consolidate the international financial architecture marks already a real change of doctrine, close to a new neoliberal compromise and partially nearing the postwar embedded liberalism recommended by Keynes. But this compromise appears all both ambiguous and unfinished, as much in its foundations that in its functioning. The object of this analysis is precisely to surround the political economy of this architecture. One examines first the official contours of the new architecture, by showing that this program is first a political reply, managed by the American diplomacy and piloted by the G 7, to the systemic contagion of the 90's. One shows then how the project of architecture, considering the theoretical underlying foundations as well as the adopted method, can be analyzed as a pragmatic compromise whose application remains at present unfulfilled, and which cannot be considered as a full reply to the challenges of systemic risk. embedded liberalism recommended by Keynes. But this compromise appears all both ambiguous and unfinished, as much in its foundations that in its functioning. The object of this analysis is precisely to surround the political economy of this architecture. One examines first the official contours of the new architecture, by showing that this program is first a political reply, managed by the American diplomacy and piloted by the G 7, to the systemic contagion of the 90's. One shows then how the project of architecture, considering the theoretical underlying foundations as well as the adopted method, can be analyzed as a pragmatic compromise whose application remains at present unfulfilled, and which cannot be considered as a full reply to the challenges of systemic risk. [fre] L'objectif de la nouvelle architecture du système financier international est de maîtriser l'instabilité financière internationale en améliorant la transparence et la surveillance des marchés, et en suscitant une plus grande responsabilité des acteurs, tant privés que publics, dans la prévention et la gestion des crises. Mais il est très improbable que la nouvelle architecture prenne la forme d'un ensemble de règles de droit dont la combinaison déboucherait sur un nouveau système s'imposant à la communauté internationale, à l'image de la création du FMI en 1944. Il s'agit d'une réponse pragmatique à l'instabilité financière internationale et non pas d'une avancée institutionnelle quant aux modes de gouvernance monétaire et financière à l'échelle internationale. Si l'ambition de consolider l'architecture financière internationale marque d'ores et déjà un infléchissement très net de doctrine, qui s'apparente à un nouveau compromis néo-libéral et se rapproche partiellement du libéralisme enchâssé de l'après-guerre, prôné par J. M. Keynes, ce compromis paraît tout à la fois ambigu et inachevé, autant dans ses fondements que dans sa mise en œuvre. Tel est l'objet de cette analyse que de cerner l'économie politique de cette architecture. On examine d'abord les contours officiels de la nouvelle architecture en montrant que ce programme est d'abord une réponse politique, impulsée par la diplomatie américaine et pilotée par le G 7, aux contagions systémiques des années 1990. On montre ensuite en quoi le projet d'architecture, compte tenu des fondements théoriques qui le sous-tendent et de la méthode mise en œuvre, peut être analysé comme un compromis pragmatique dont l'application reste encore inachevée et qui ne saurait pleinement répondre aux défis du risque systémique.
Suggested Citation
André Cartapanis, 2001.
"Economie politique de l'architecture financière internationale,"
Revue Économique, Programme National Persée, vol. 52(2), pages 447-465.
Handle:
RePEc:prs:reveco:reco_0035-2764_2001_num_52_2_410328
DOI: 10.3406/reco.2001.410328
Note: DOI:10.3406/reco.2001.410328
Download full text from publisher
As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to look for a different version below or search for a different version of it.
Other versions of this item:
Citations
Citations are extracted by the
CitEc Project, subscribe to its
RSS feed for this item.
Cited by:
- Catherine Figuière & Laëtitia Guilhot, 2010.
"L'Asie d'une crise à l'autre : l'impact sur l'intégration régionale,"
Post-Print
halshs-00493869, HAL.
- André Cartapanis, 2011.
"La crise financière et les politiques macroprudentielles. Inflexion réglementaire ou nouveau paradigme ?,"
Revue économique, Presses de Sciences-Po, vol. 62(3), pages 349-382.
- Andre Cartapanis, 2004.
"Le declenchement des crises de change : qu'avons-nous appris depuis dix ans ?,"
Economie Internationale, CEPII research center, issue 97, pages 5-48.
- Cartapanis A. & Herland M., 2001.
"Systemic Risk and New International Financial Architecture: Reconciling KEYNES and Neo-Liberalism?,"
European Research Studies Journal, European Research Studies Journal, vol. 0(1-2), pages 5-26, January -.
More about this item
JEL classification:
- F33 - International Economics - - International Finance - - - International Monetary Arrangements and Institutions
- G15 - Financial Economics - - General Financial Markets - - - International Financial Markets
Statistics
Access and download statistics
Corrections
All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:prs:reveco:reco_0035-2764_2001_num_52_2_410328. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.
If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.
We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .
If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.
For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Equipe PERSEE (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://www.persee.fr/collection/reco .
Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through
the various RePEc services.