Author
Abstract
Public pension plan sponsors claim that their perpetual existence and taxing power exempt them from financial economics. They therefore ignore current market conditions and rely on patience and intergenerational risk sharing to overcome risk. The author shows that their use of discount rates that far exceed current market levels produces financial opacity, retirement insecurity, and intergenerational inequity, leaving the solvency of these plans dependent on the systematic mistreatment of future generations of taxpayers.Long-term US Treasuries are yielding less than 3%, while US public pension plans are discounting their liabilities and basing their funding on rates of 7%–8%. This article focuses on the United States but notes that similar discrepancies between public plan discount rates and the local default-free rate appear in most developed countries, particularly in Western Europe. These discrepancies produce financial opacity, retirement insecurity, and intergenerational inequity.Insurance companies manage their annuity business roughly in accordance with the principles of financial economics, which call for discounting insured liabilities at rates that are default-free or nearly so. Public plan sponsors ignore these principles. They invest substantially in equities and often in such alternative investments as private equity, real estate, and hedge funds. They estimate, generously, the risk premiums they expect to earn on these investments. They reflect the hoped-for risk premiums in the discount rates that underlie their financial reporting, plan contributions, and pricing of negotiated plan improvements.Public pension plan authorities claim various justifications for their deviations from financial economics, observing that, unlike insurance companies, they have taxing power and will exist in perpetuity. They can share their investment risks among multiple generations of taxpayers—long enough for those risks to become minimal and manageable. Public pension plan authorities can thus count on earning the risk premiums embedded in the higher expected rates of return. In the worst case, they can fall back on their taxing power.This long-term argument implicitly relies on an extreme mean reversion process. It implies that the variance of a risky portfolio’s cumulative return decreases as the measurement period extends, rather than merely increasing more slowly than under a simple random walk model. The idea that risk shrinks over sufficiently long periods has been refuted by financial economists.The intergenerational-risk-sharing argument is also flawed. This article considers a two-period illustration in which the first taxpayer generation funds the pensions earned during its tenure. The discount rate used to determine the pension contribution includes a risk premium—in effect, the first generation uses the risk premium to reduce its contribution. It then exits the scene, having borne no risk and leaving the new generation to settle up in the second period. The second generation enjoys gains or faces losses with an average value of zero; that is, it bears the risk of gains or losses but can expect no risk premium. The risk premium, which can exceed half the true pension cost, has been confiscated by the first generation, which bore no risk. In practice, where immediate settlement is not required, risks continually pass to future generations, with surpluses swept off the table and deficits allowed to run for as many generations as possible.Thus, the true benefit of the long government time horizon is not that it overcomes risk but, rather, that it delivers a steady supply of future involuntary risk bearers on whom the government can exert its taxing power—at least until it runs out of sufficiently affluent generations of taxpayers. In such failures, the victims can include not only taxpayers but also plan members and municipal bondholders.Apart from the risk of demographic collapse, the dependence on future generations of taxpayers violates the fundamental principle of public finance: each generation should pay in full for the services it consumes, without passing either direct costs or funding risks to future generations. Ensuring sustainability and fairness for all generations of plan participants and taxpayers requires economically correct discount rates for financial reporting, determination of contributions, and pricing of benefit increases.Editor’s note: This article was reviewed and accepted by Executive Editor Robert Litterman.
Suggested Citation
Lawrence N. Bader, 2015.
"How Public Pension Plans Can (and Why They Shouldn’t) Ignore Financial Economics,"
Financial Analysts Journal, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 71(5), pages 14-16, September.
Handle:
RePEc:taf:ufajxx:v:71:y:2015:i:5:p:14-16
DOI: 10.2469/faj.v71.n5.1
Download full text from publisher
As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.
Corrections
All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:taf:ufajxx:v:71:y:2015:i:5:p:14-16. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.
If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.
We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .
If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.
For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Chris Longhurst (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.tandfonline.com/ufaj20 .
Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through
the various RePEc services.