IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/taf/ufajxx/v64y2008i2p20-29.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Affect in a Behavioral Asset-Pricing Model

Author

Listed:
  • Meir Statman
  • Kenneth L. Fisher
  • Deniz Anginer

Abstract

Stocks, like houses, cars, watches, and other products, exude “affect”—that is, they are considered good or bad, beautiful or ugly; they are admired or disliked. Affect plays an overt role in the pricing of houses, cars, and watches, but according to standard financial theory, it plays no role in the pricing of financial assets. This article outlines a behavioral asset-pricing model in which expected returns are high not only when objective risk is high but also when subjective risk is high. High subjective risk comes with negative affect. Investors prefer stocks with positive affect, which boosts the prices of such stocks and depresses their returns.Stocks, like houses, cars, watches, and other products, exude “affect.” Affect is the feeling of good or bad, beautiful or ugly, admired or disliked, and it occurs rapidly and automatically, often without consciousness. Affect plays a role in the pricing models of houses, cars, and watches but, according to standard financial theory, plays no role in the pricing of financial assets.In this article, we outline a behavioral asset-pricing model in which expected returns are high when objective risk is high and also when subjective risk is high. High subjective risk comes with negative affect. Investors prefer stocks with positive affect, and their preference boosts the prices of such stocks and depresses their subsequent returns.The preferences of investors were gathered from surveys conducted by Fortune magazine in 1983–2006 and in additional surveys we conducted in 2007. From the Fortune data, we found that the returns of admired stocks, those highly rated by the Fortune respondents, were lower than the returns of spurned stocks, those rated low. This finding is consistent with the hypothesis that stocks with negative affect have high subjective risk and their extra returns compensate for that risk. We also found that admired companies have higher market capitalizations but lower book-to-market ratios than spurned companies. This finding is consistent with the hypothesis that size and book value to market value are proxies for affect.We gathered supporting evidence from our own surveys. In these surveys, we presented investors with only the names of companies and their industries and asked them to rate the affect of these companies. The questionnaire said, “Look at the name of the company and its industry and quickly rate the feeling associated with it on a scale ranging from bad to good. Don’t spend time thinking about the rating. Just go with your quick, intuitive feeling.” We found a positive correlation between these affect scores and the companies’ Fortune scores. Moreover, we found that positive affect creates a halo over stocks that results in perceptions that they promise high future returns coupled with low risk.

Suggested Citation

  • Meir Statman & Kenneth L. Fisher & Deniz Anginer, 2008. "Affect in a Behavioral Asset-Pricing Model," Financial Analysts Journal, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 64(2), pages 20-29, March.
  • Handle: RePEc:taf:ufajxx:v:64:y:2008:i:2:p:20-29
    DOI: 10.2469/faj.v64.n2.8
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://hdl.handle.net/10.2469/faj.v64.n2.8
    Download Restriction: Access to full text is restricted to subscribers.

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.2469/faj.v64.n2.8?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:taf:ufajxx:v:64:y:2008:i:2:p:20-29. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Chris Longhurst (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.tandfonline.com/ufaj20 .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.