IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/taf/ufajxx/v61y2005i6p74-77.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Retirement Income Guarantees Are Expensive

Author

Listed:
  • Don Ezra

Abstract

Traditional defined-benefit pension plans depend on funding by employers to preserve the security of their income guarantees. The U.S. Social Security system depends on demographic stability. In both cases, security has proven to be elusive. In neither case does one find contingency reserves created in good times to help sustain security in bad times. Instead, society turns to defined-contribution arrangements, thereby throwing the risk onto individuals. Individuals have their own problems to cope with, however, involving uncertainty of both longevity and investment returns. The unsurprising lesson overall is: Eliminating risk is expensive. It is all too easy, and all too tempting, to forget in good times that retirement income guarantees are expensive. Employee benefit plans, the U.S. Social Security system, and individual retirement arrangements—all confirm this lesson.When the U.S. Congress passed the Employee Retirement Income Security Act in 1974, it strengthened the funding requirements for corporate defined-benefit (DB) pension plans. Congress failed to recognize, however, that uncertain investment returns create risk, which in turn requires funding flexibility so that contingency reserves can be built up in good times and drawn down in bad times. Instead, Congress imposed further restrictions in the 1980s, restrictions that ensured an underfunding bias in DB plans.In addition, actuaries, ignoring equity risk in their valuations, have assumed simply that the risk premium will be realized. In consequence, actuarial funding targets make benefits insecure. Moreover, the confusion between a funding target (which ignores risk) and the value of the benefit (which is based on a risk-free return) leads to defined benefits being underpriced.Sponsors need flexibility to underwrite defined benefits for employees. And employees need to recognize that the cost of the defined benefits is higher than commonly thought.In the Social Security system, the mechanism for security is a demographic balance between retirees and contributors. This balance has become unsustainable in the United States, as in many countries. But no contingency reserve was built while Baby Boomers were contributing to the system, so Social Security benefits are now subject to political risk.Both in traditional employer plans and in Social Security, income guarantees are under attack. This development is a pity because defined benefits are healthy for society. They enable individual risks to be shared by groups, thereby making retirement incomes secure.In the corporate world, defined-benefit plans are rapidly being replaced by defined-contribution plans. Defined-contribution arrangements, however, leave individuals facing two forms of uncertainty in generating retirement income—longevity and investment returns. Experts understand investment uncertainty and speak of distributions and standard deviations of returns. Lifespan uncertainty needs to be understood, and explained, in a similar way. What is the standard deviation of life expectancy? Planners should be as familiar with this concept as they are with the standard deviation of equity returns.Coping with both kinds of uncertainty is difficult and costly, particularly when interest rates are low and the present value (cost) of a fixed retirement income increases. To guarantee their retirement income, many individuals have to take on investment risk or reduce their hoped-for standard of living—or both.Risk is not nice. But retirement income guarantees are expensive.

Suggested Citation

  • Don Ezra, 2005. "Retirement Income Guarantees Are Expensive," Financial Analysts Journal, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 61(6), pages 74-77, November.
  • Handle: RePEc:taf:ufajxx:v:61:y:2005:i:6:p:74-77
    DOI: 10.2469/faj.v61.n6.2773
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://hdl.handle.net/10.2469/faj.v61.n6.2773
    Download Restriction: Access to full text is restricted to subscribers.

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.2469/faj.v61.n6.2773?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:taf:ufajxx:v:61:y:2005:i:6:p:74-77. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Chris Longhurst (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.tandfonline.com/ufaj20 .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.