IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/pubcho/v52y1987i2p193-199.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Capital intensity and the federal sector: Some further evidence

Author

Listed:
  • Gabriel Obermann

Abstract

The above considerations provide certainly no more than a small contribution to the puzzles of the economics of public bureaucracy. Nevertheless, the empirical evidence presented may reflect some general features of the provision of public services; still, it would be desirable to get additional information from other countries in order to carry positive theory further. The evidence of a high level of real property intensity certainly asks for an explanation. Most helpful in this respect would probably be a thorough analysis comparing particular service domains of the public and of the private sector in order to find out whether comparable services are provided at a similar degree of real property intensity. Since such comparisons are not to my knowledge available (as yet) it may be appropriate to list some speculative arguments that may serve to explain real property intensity. Several typical features of the provision of public services are presumably of particular importance. Public administration mainly consists of providing services; in most cases such services are produced — spontaneously or upon request — by public bodies themselves. It is noteworthy and of relevance for real property intensity that the public authorities (can) only carry out relatively few duties ‘off the premises’ (e.g. police inspections, control of national frontiers), whereas the bulk of public services are produced ‘on the premises’. This requires, apart from other provisions, adequate buildings with office space, court halls, waiting rooms etc., in some countries also schools, hospitals a.o. The essential difference between the public sector and many private service companies is probably, that (under the prevailing standards) the public administration can hardly reduce its requirements of real property by going directly to the customer/client in providing its services or even by contracting external professional (who do not require an office) to any large extent. Another characteristic of the public administration may also contribute to the high level of real property intensity. The input of real property must be seen in the light of well-known claims for public services to be generally and easily accessible to the public and for official authorities to work in close contact with their clients. For many public responsibilities, therefore, there are local and district offices and subsidiaries (e.g. legal courts, local authorities) spread out over the whole administration area, apart from the economically useful concentration — regional as well as functional — in ministries and central offices usually located in the capital. This obligation, in reality probably quite strong, for the public administration to be present at the local level (also for higher-ranking authorities) and to de-centralise personnel and capital may yield positive external effects for clients of public authorities (in the form of lower private costs), but at the same time overincreases factor inputs, particularly also the input of real property. To some, albeit smaller, extent the high real property endowment of the public sector may also be determined by the well-known practice to use for administrative purpose, preferably and independent of cost considerations, buildings which are public property rather than rented office space. The empirical evidence available on capital intensity is yet too scarce for a test of the ‘factor-supplier pressure group hypothesis’ (Tullock, 1977) for the domain of public administration. The evidence of Cummings and Ruhter (1980) for the areas of higher education, hospitals and museums corresponds rather well to the ‘factor-supplier pressure group’ hypothesis. A comparison between the federal and the local level shows that the real property intensity (capital intensity) is significantly higher for the federal sector — in education by 25 to 53%, in the domain of hospitals up to 38% higher. Tullock assumes that factor input is determined in different ways on the federal and the local level by civil servants and factor suppliers. The specific electoral interests and bargaining power of these groups suggest that the central administration will be more capital intensive in its provision of services than the local authorities which will rather give preference to the factor ‘labor’. It is not possible to settle this issue with evidence being available only for the federal administration level; yet it can be argued that, abstracting from institutional conditions, the diagnosis of a high capital intensity on the federal level is indeed consistent with Tullock's hypothesis. To the extent that no other, hitherto not identified factors further narrow the scope for discretionary action (e.g. higher quality standards of services provided at the federal level) the above figures reflect the room for manoeuvre — in the sense of the Tullock hypothesis — within which the bureaucrats successfully imposed their factor-related preferences in the respective domains. The test by Dilorenzo (1981) using data on local government spending is itself not sufficient since the evidence only refers to the local level. Further evidence on factor intensity in other domains of the public sector is given in Borcherding et al. (1982). Copyright Martinus Nijhoff Publishers 1987

Suggested Citation

  • Gabriel Obermann, 1987. "Capital intensity and the federal sector: Some further evidence," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 52(2), pages 193-199, January.
  • Handle: RePEc:kap:pubcho:v:52:y:1987:i:2:p:193-199
    DOI: 10.1007/BF00123877
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://hdl.handle.net/10.1007/BF00123877
    Download Restriction: Access to full text is restricted to subscribers.

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1007/BF00123877?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    As the access to this document is restricted, you may want to search for a different version of it.

    References listed on IDEAS

    as
    1. Thomas Dilorenzo, 1981. "An empirical assessment of the factor-supplier pressure group hypothesis," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 37(3), pages 559-568, January.
    2. William Orzechowski, 1974. "Laborintensity, productivity, and the growth of the federal sector," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 19(1), pages 123-126, September.
    3. F. Cummings & Wayne Ruhter, 1980. "Some tests of the factor-supplier pressure group hypothesis," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 35(3), pages 257-266, January.
    4. James Buchanan & Gordon Tullock, 1977. "The expanding public sector: Wagner squared," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 31(1), pages 147-150, September.
    Full references (including those not matched with items on IDEAS)

    Most related items

    These are the items that most often cite the same works as this one and are cited by the same works as this one.
    1. François Facchini & Mickael Melki & Andrew Pickering, 2013. "The Labor Share and the Size of Government," Discussion Papers 13/02, Department of Economics, University of York.
    2. Ferdi Celikay, 2020. "Dimensions of tax burden: a review on OECD countries," Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Science, Emerald Group Publishing Limited, vol. 25(49), pages 27-43, March.
    3. Etienne Farvaque & Frédéric Gannon, 2018. "Profiling giants: the networks and influence of Buchanan and Tullock," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 175(3), pages 277-302, June.
    4. Bruno Frey & Werner Pommerehne, 1982. "How powerful are public bureaucrats as voters?," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 38(3), pages 253-262, January.
    5. Michael L. Marlow, 2013. "Public sector unions and government size," Applied Economics Letters, Taylor & Francis Journals, vol. 20(5), pages 466-470, March.
    6. Afonso, António & Furceri, Davide, 2010. "Government size, composition, volatility and economic growth," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 26(4), pages 517-532, December.
    7. François Facchini & Mickael Melki & Andrew Pickering, 2017. "Labour Costs and the Size of Government," Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Department of Economics, University of Oxford, vol. 79(2), pages 251-275, April.
    8. David Nellor, 1984. "Public bureau budgets and jurisdiction size: An empirical note," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 42(2), pages 175-183, January.
    9. Rodolfo Gonzalez & Roger Folsom & Stephen Mehay, 1989. "Bureaucracy, publicness and local government expenditures revisited: Comment," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 62(1), pages 71-77, July.
    10. Kristof Witte & Wim Moesen, 2010. "Sizing the government," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 145(1), pages 39-55, October.
    11. Christopher Hood, 1991. "Stabilization and Cutbacks," Journal of Theoretical Politics, , vol. 3(1), pages 37-63, January.
    12. Kenneth V. Greene & Vincent G. Munley, 1979. "Generating Growth in Public Expenditures: the Role of Employee and Constituent Demand," Public Finance Review, , vol. 7(1), pages 92-109, January.
    13. Potters, Jan & Sloof, Randolph, 1996. "Interest groups: A survey of empirical models that try to assess their influence," European Journal of Political Economy, Elsevier, vol. 12(3), pages 403-442, November.
    14. Manuel Jaen-Garcia, 2011. "Empirical Analysis of Wagner’s Law for the Spain’s Regions," International Journal of Academic Research in Accounting, Finance and Management Sciences, Human Resource Management Academic Research Society, International Journal of Academic Research in Accounting, Finance and Management Sciences, vol. 1(1), pages 1-17, November.
    15. Rashidul Islam Sheikh, 2019. "Analysis of the Determinants of Public Education Expenditures in Bangladesh," Journal of Public Administration and Governance, Macrothink Institute, vol. 9(3), pages 151-178, December.
    16. Thomas Dilorenzo, 1981. "An empirical assessment of the factor-supplier pressure group hypothesis," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 37(3), pages 559-568, January.
    17. repec:hal:spmain:info:hdl:2441/6urb9g3nsd9s9ai3tbjqnnd41g is not listed on IDEAS
    18. Etienne Farvaque & Frédéric Gannon, 2018. "Profiling giants," Post-Print hal-02078382, HAL.
    19. James Bennett, 1980. "Review," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 35(4), pages 511-512, January.
    20. Mark Schneider, 1989. "Intercity competition and the size of the local public work force," Public Choice, Springer, vol. 63(3), pages 253-265, December.
    21. Gomes, Pedro Maia & Wellschmied, Felix, 2020. "Public-Sector Compensation over the Life Cycle," IZA Discussion Papers 13042, Institute of Labor Economics (IZA).

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:kap:pubcho:v:52:y:1987:i:2:p:193-199. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    If CitEc recognized a bibliographic reference but did not link an item in RePEc to it, you can help with this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Sonal Shukla or Springer Nature Abstracting and Indexing (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.springer.com .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.