IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/col/000425/010911.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

Dynamic Provisioning: A Buffer Rather Than a Countercyclical Tool?

Author

Listed:
  • Santiago Fernandez de Lis
  • Alicia Garcia-Herrero

Abstract

The global financial storm which started in 2007 and which we are still experiencing is one of the very best examples in recent economic history of how much the financial system can exacerbate real economy cycles. Such pro-cyclicality has triggered a lively debate on which tools can be used to smooth this pattern, focused on macro-prudential policies. There was limited experience in the use of macro-prudential instruments before the crisis. The most prominent examples are the use of Loan-to-Value ratios (LTV) in some Asian countries and dynamic provisions in Spain (see Caruana, 2010). The latter received a lot of attention and in the early stages of the crisis were seen as a model for the then incipient international regulatory reform. But the debate shifted rapidly from provisions to capital and the reform crystallized soon in the adoption of a capital buffer in the context of Basel III, whereas the discussion on provisions languished and seems now in a deadlock. Two reasons explain this decreasing interest: the difficulties for accounting harmonisation between the Americans and the Europeans, which partly explains why the Basel Committee took the easier route of capital; and the evidence, as the crisis deepened, that dynamic provisions did not prevent serious problems in certain segments of the Spanish banking system. The analysis of the Spanish case raises now more complex issues than a few years ago: why was dynamic provisioning insufficient? Was a problem of design or application? Or were the bubble and the crisis too big to be addressed by this tool? Did dynamic provisioning have unintended consequences? In particular, did it delay the solution of the problems of saving banks? Was it a useful buffer, but not a genuine countercyclical tool? This paper focuses in the latter question, but to do so we need to address the previous questions to a certain extent, since they are very much interlinked. The question of whether dynamic provision was a buffer or a dampener is closely related inter alia to the rules versus discretion debate. Under a formula-driven system, the required level of provisions would vary according to some predetermined metric. It would provide a preset discipline independent on judgment. However, its success will depend crucially on the possibility of calibrating the business cycle ex ante, an issue to which we will return later. A rules-based system is superior to a discretionary mechanism in situations where the policy maker faces a problem of lack of credibility of its commitment. However, a rules-based system may face constraints that ultimately lead to discretionary adjustments. In particular, asymmetric market discipline (that fact that markets are too lenient in the good times and too strict in the bad times) may preclude the use of the accumulated buffer in the downturn, thus impeding the anti-cyclical compensation. We provide some evidence that this was a factor in the case of Spain: when liquidity dried-up and funding in the interbank market disappeared, markets required a higher level of own funds, limiting the anti-cyclical impact of dynamic provisions. To be fair, the sheer size of the crisis was also a factor limiting the compensation of rising NPLs, with the final effect that total provisions rose considerably in the bust, contrary to what was intended. Spain is not the only country that adopted dynamic provisions, but it was the pioneer and the only one for which there is experience on a boom and bust cycle. In order to obtain more general conclusions we do not limit ourselves, however, to the analysis of the Spanish case, but compare it to two Latin American countries that adopted dynamic provisions in the late 2000s: Peru and Colombia. The comparison with these countries allows extracting more general conclusions on the pros and cons of alternative designs, and allows also considering whether there are particular aspects that need to be taken into account in applying this tool to emerging market economies.

Suggested Citation

  • Santiago Fernandez de Lis & Alicia Garcia-Herrero, 2013. "Dynamic Provisioning: A Buffer Rather Than a Countercyclical Tool?," Economía Journal, The Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association - LACEA, vol. 0(Spring 20), pages 35-67, January.
  • Handle: RePEc:col:000425:010911
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: http://economia.lacea.org/contents.htm
    Download Restriction: no
    ---><---

    Other versions of this item:

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Drehmann, Mathias & Juselius, Mikael, 2014. "Evaluating early warning indicators of banking crises: Satisfying policy requirements," International Journal of Forecasting, Elsevier, vol. 30(3), pages 759-780.
    2. Basak, Deepal & Murray, Alexander & Zhao, Yunhui, 2017. "Does Financial Tranquility Call for More Stringent Regulation?," MPRA Paper 81373, University Library of Munich, Germany.
    3. Agénor, Pierre-Richard & Pereira da Silva, Luiz, 2017. "Cyclically adjusted provisions and financial stability," Journal of Financial Stability, Elsevier, vol. 28(C), pages 143-162.
    4. Xiaofeng Hui & Aoran Zhang, 2020. "Construction and Empirical Research on the Dynamic Provisioning Model of China’s Banking Sector under the Macro-Prudential Framework," Sustainability, MDPI, vol. 12(20), pages 1-26, October.
    5. Agénor, Pierre-Richard & Pereira da Silva, Luiz, 2017. "Cyclically adjusted provisions and financial stability," Journal of Financial Stability, Elsevier, vol. 28(C), pages 143-162.
    6. Tito Cordella & Pablo M. Federico & Carlos A. Vegh & Guillermo Vuletin, 2014. "Reserve Requirements in the Brave New Macroprudential World," World Bank Publications - Books, The World Bank Group, number 17584.
    7. Ebrahimi Kahou, Mahdi & Lehar, Alfred, 2017. "Macroprudential policy: A review," Journal of Financial Stability, Elsevier, vol. 29(C), pages 92-105.
    8. Agénor, Pierre-Richard & Zilberman, Roy, 2015. "Loan Loss Provisioning Rules, Procyclicality, and Financial Volatility," Journal of Banking & Finance, Elsevier, vol. 61(C), pages 301-315.
    9. Deepal Basak & Mr. Yunhui Zhao, 2018. "Does Financial Tranquility Call for Stringent Regulation?," IMF Working Papers 2018/123, International Monetary Fund.

    More about this item

    Keywords

    Dynamic; Provisioning; Cyclical; Latin; America;
    All these keywords.

    JEL classification:

    • E52 - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics - - Monetary Policy, Central Banking, and the Supply of Money and Credit - - - Monetary Policy
    • E58 - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics - - Monetary Policy, Central Banking, and the Supply of Money and Credit - - - Central Banks and Their Policies

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:col:000425:010911. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: LACEA (email available below). General contact details of provider: https://edirc.repec.org/data/laceaea.html .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.