IDEAS home Printed from https://ideas.repec.org/a/bla/jacrfn/v30y2018i3p8-26.html
   My bibliography  Save this article

The Dynamism of Nations: Toward a Theory of Indigenous Innovation

Author

Listed:
  • Edmund Phelps

Abstract

In this essay, 2006 Nobelist Edmund Phelps expands upon the ideas about innovation and creativity he introduced in his 2013 book Mass Flourishing. Phelps argues that while economies have continued to evolve, the concepts in economics have lagged behind. In standard economic models, the reward for work is fundamentally the market wage. There is no room for any human agency by which a person might gain rewards other than the going wage. Thus, standard models miss the character of a modern economy. The treatment of “innovation” is especially lacking. Standard economics uses the word “innovation” to denote a shift in a “technology” parameter. Yet these parametric shifts are exogenous to the economy–not new products or new methods conceived in the economy, thus endogenous to the economy. Western nations that have gone from brilliance to very slow growth have little idea of how to redevelop the old élan of their best decades. With only the standard toolkit, economists may offer relief from some of the symptoms of the illness, but not a cure. Standard economics cannot cure the illness because it cannot know the causes. The critically missing element in standard economics is indigenous innovation. This refers to new ideas not just to adaptations. A great many businesspeople take the view that a company “innovates” when it detects and acts on a new opportunity–one that fills a need. But the concept of an indigenous innovation–a new idea that brings new practice–is miles away from the concept of detecting and acting on an opportunity that brings new practice. Indigenous innovation, where it occurs, is driven by people's creativity. Innovators use their imagination to conceive of new products or methods and their ingenuity and savvy to implement the new product or method, that is, to make it and market it. New ideas are not the same thing as science. Science does not tell us whether there will be a market for any of the new possibilities; business knowledge is indispensable here. Even in Western countries, myriad business discoveries may have led to as many new products and methods as from scientific discoveries between the 1820s and 1960s. Phelps believes the “spirit” of dynamism derived from modern ethical values including individualism, vitalism, and selfexpression. They also include what Phelps calls “visionaryism” or the desire to create entirely new things. Modern societies developed as the result of these modern values. And where these values reached a critical mass, modern economies sprouted up which brought mass innovating and thus rapid economic growth. The dynamism also enriched work. Ordinary people had engaging employment and most of them prospered and many flourished. Phelps sees several causes for the loss of dynamism, particularly regulation and what he calls “social protection.” He is not referring to social security but to efforts to inhibit change. Not only does social protection stymie potential agents of change on the outside (e.g., by blocking potential startups) but CEOs who might have been innovators are reduced to being lobbyists and rent seekers. He thinks the private sector may also suffer from “decadence” including corruption, weak governance, and short‐termism. Phelps refers collectively to the old values opposing modern values as “corporatist values.” Now pervasive in all the nations of the West, corporatism is behind the selfserving vested interests, clientelism, and cronyism. Two propositions follow from this assessment: 1. Nations that lack the dynamism for mass indigenous innovation will not achieve the prosperity of which modern economies are capable. “Reform” will be fruitless without the right culture. It will be necessary to bring back into schools and the home the literature of adventure and exploration. 2. The once‐dynamic nations of the West cannot regain the stunning indigenous innovation of the 19th and 20th centuries without first doing battle with corporatist values. Western nations will have to reassert the modern values.

Suggested Citation

  • Edmund Phelps, 2018. "The Dynamism of Nations: Toward a Theory of Indigenous Innovation," Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Morgan Stanley, vol. 30(3), pages 8-26, September.
  • Handle: RePEc:bla:jacrfn:v:30:y:2018:i:3:p:8-26
    DOI: 10.1111/jacf.12306
    as

    Download full text from publisher

    File URL: https://doi.org/10.1111/jacf.12306
    Download Restriction: no

    File URL: https://libkey.io/10.1111/jacf.12306?utm_source=ideas
    LibKey link: if access is restricted and if your library uses this service, LibKey will redirect you to where you can use your library subscription to access this item
    ---><---

    Citations

    Citations are extracted by the CitEc Project, subscribe to its RSS feed for this item.
    as


    Cited by:

    1. Tae-Seok Jang & Sehwan Oh, 2023. "Transition to Sustainable Growth in South Korea: Investment and Trade under Uncertainty," Millennial Asia, , vol. 14(3), pages 360-378, September.
    2. Timothy R Wojan & Bonnie Nichols, 2018. "Design, innovation, and rural creative places: Are the arts the cherry on top, or the secret sauce?," PLOS ONE, Public Library of Science, vol. 13(2), pages 1-23, February.
    3. Harrison Paul Adjimah & Victor Yawo Atiase & Dennis Yao Dzansi, 2022. "Examining the Role of Regulation in the Commercialisation of Indigenous Innovation in Sub-Saharan African Economies: Evidence from the Ghanaian Small-Scale Industry," Administrative Sciences, MDPI, vol. 12(3), pages 1-21, September.

    More about this item

    Statistics

    Access and download statistics

    Corrections

    All material on this site has been provided by the respective publishers and authors. You can help correct errors and omissions. When requesting a correction, please mention this item's handle: RePEc:bla:jacrfn:v:30:y:2018:i:3:p:8-26. See general information about how to correct material in RePEc.

    If you have authored this item and are not yet registered with RePEc, we encourage you to do it here. This allows to link your profile to this item. It also allows you to accept potential citations to this item that we are uncertain about.

    We have no bibliographic references for this item. You can help adding them by using this form .

    If you know of missing items citing this one, you can help us creating those links by adding the relevant references in the same way as above, for each refering item. If you are a registered author of this item, you may also want to check the "citations" tab in your RePEc Author Service profile, as there may be some citations waiting for confirmation.

    For technical questions regarding this item, or to correct its authors, title, abstract, bibliographic or download information, contact: Wiley Content Delivery (email available below). General contact details of provider: http://www.blackwellpublishing.com/journal.asp?ref=1078-1196 .

    Please note that corrections may take a couple of weeks to filter through the various RePEc services.

    IDEAS is a RePEc service. RePEc uses bibliographic data supplied by the respective publishers.